Subido por Alexei Camacho

1 gip module 4 core reading

Anuncio
Green Industrial Policy
Promoting Competitiveness and
Structural Transformation
Core reading
Module 4: Green Industrial Policy Instruments
1
Introduction
The process of green industrialization is a complex undertaking. It calls for a holistic and integrated
approach to policymaking across the economic, social, and environmental sectors.
At the same time, the type of transformative change required to instigate a green industrial policy
naturally brings with it a certain degree of uncertainty and risk. This change may not occur voluntarily,
and a range of “carrots” and “sticks” – i.e. incentives and deterrents – will therefore need to be
employed to trigger the actions necessary for green structural change.
This change will necessarily be government-led, and public policy, as a shaper and driver of
economic and societal transformation, should therefore sit at the heart of the process. Public policy
may be implemented through a range of mutually reinforcing policy instruments, to meet the
increased need of green industrial policy to build synergistic links across a range of thematic areas
which bridge environmental, economic, and social concerns.
The range of policy instruments should be drawn on to enhance value addition within sectors in a
radically different way. For example, a comprehensive circular economy strategy may feature
taxation for landfill, carbon footprint, and product and materials, include VAT exemptions, feed-intariffs, and public procurement programmes, and finally promote R&D for eco-design programmes
[1].
To this end, policy instruments are constantly evolving in response to the demand for systemic
solutions to the complex challenges of our time. At the same time, governments are adapting and
refining policy instruments according to their past experiences, as well as their capabilities, needs,
and level of industrialisation.
Finally, it should be noted that in practice, the boundaries between instrument categories are not
always clearly defined. Instruments often possess the features of more than one category. For
example, governments may mandate emission quotas, but introduce tradable permits to enhance
1
efficiency. Voluntary standards may also form part of the gradual introduction of regulation with
increasing degrees of compulsion over time. Indeed, governments are now increasingly employing
instruments from more than one category, as part of a strategic and coordinated mix of several
instrument types. The specific design of the green industrial policy will depend on the issue to be
addressed, and on the specific country circumstances at play.
2
A policy instrument framework
Economic/
Fiscal
(Marketbased)
Commandand-Control
Voluntary/
Informational
2
Figure 1. Categories of policy instruments
There are three broad categories of policy instruments. Regulatory instruments (“command-andcontrol”) encompass instruments related to norms and standards, environmental liability, and control
and enforcement. Regulation, provided it is strictly enforced, has a strong steering impulse. The
steering impulse of voluntary or informational instruments, on the other hand, is soft. Market-based
instruments (“economic/fiscal”) lie somewhere in between, with their steering impulse depending on
the scale of market manipulation and the responsiveness (i.e. the elasticity) of supply and demand.
Market-based instruments typically have a good degree of dominance in the instruments mixes of
green industrial policy.
The matrix on the following page highlights the various types of instruments that can be used for
green industrial policymaking, and identifies where each of these sit in the spectrum of steering
impulse: for instance, whether they are “soft” or “hard”, and whether they reward or penalise, motivate
or support.
Recommended reading
Luken, R. A. and Clarence-Smith, E., “Green Industrialization in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Guide for
Policy Makers” (2019) UONGOZI Institute. https://www.africaportal.org/publications/greenindustrialization-sub-saharan-africa-guide-policy-makers/.
Cosbey, A., Wooders, P., Bridle, R. and Casier, L., “In with the Good, Out with the Bad: Phasing
Out Polluting Sectors as Green Industrial Policy” in PAGE, Green Industrial Policy: Concept,
Policies, Country Experiences (2017) UNEP and DIE, p. 72, for an overview of the spectrum of
types of disruptive green industrial policies. https://www.unpage.org/files/public/green_industrial_policy_book_aw_web.pdf
UNIDO, “A Shift in the Production Paradigm” (2019) Making It Magazine. An interview with
Manuel Albaladejo. https://www.makingitmagazine.net/?p=10886
Figure 2. A policy matrix for green industrial policies
3
Source: UNIDO, Green Industry: Policies for Supporting Green Industry (2011)
3
Command-and-control instruments
Regulatory or “command-and-control” instruments typically form the basis of environmental policy
frameworks in both developed and developing countries. Regulations address a broad range of
environmental problems and are particularly useful in addressing those issues that can be easily
identified, monitored, and enforced, such as point sources of pollution. They also provide certainty and
clarity for administrators, and businesses [2].
Generally, regulation consists of four main activities: (i) standard-setting; (ii) issuance of licenses; (iii)
compliance monitoring; and (iv) enforcement in cases of non-compliance. The combined purpose of
these four activities is to encourage and guide conduct that is favourable to the environment, or to
prohibit conduct that is detrimental [3].
For example, a review of Ghana’s environmental regulations recommended that the Environmental
Protection Agency should expand its permits (i.e. licensing) scheme to include all medium-sized and
large enterprises. Currently, it has provided permits to only 250 to 300 enterprises, out of an estimated
population of 500 to 600 medium-sized and large enterprises [3]. Similarly, Nigeria has a comprehensive
range of strict environmental quality and pollutant discharge standards that are in line with those put
forward in the World Bank guidelines, but the problem of limited enforcement remains. Only in the case
of Lagos state is there a noticeable enforcement effort [3].
Flexible, well-designed standards and regulations can also be a short-term stimulus for innovation and
technology diffusion by creating a demand for products and services. However, poorly designed
regulations can also have the opposite effect, and stifle longer-term technological innovation.
In general, regulatory instruments are less economically efficient than market-based instruments, and
often have significant informational requirements for their effective design. They can also be complex to
administer, although again this depends largely on the way in which they are structured.
However, in practice the distinction between direct regulations and market-based or economic
instruments is often blurred. Any system of economic instruments usually requires appropriate legislative
or regulatory backing. Regulations should therefore form part of a mix of policy instruments, and be
supported by an integrated overarching legal framework.
Germany’s Energy Conservation Regulations
Germany’s EnEV (Energy Conservation Regulations) 2013 represent an encompassing
example of “command-and-control” regulations, which also draw on a range of
complementary instruments to leverage their impact. They also highlight a stepwise
tightening of construction law to a carbon neutral standard by 2021, whereby standards are
incrementally introduced and tightened over time.
4
Financial incentives to comply with regulations and voluntary mechanisms are provided in
the form of subsidy programmes offered by the public bank, Kreditanstaltfür Wiederaufbau
(KfW). These programmes offer support for the refurbishment and construction of new
buildings, and for heating with renewable energy.
The government’s 2004 CO2 Reduction Programme includes two subsidised loan
schemes: the KfW programme for energy efficient refurbishment, and the KfW programme
for energy efficient new buildings. Grants and loans are staggered according to the degree
of energy efficiency: the more energy efficient the building is, the higher the grant and the
more favourable the repayment conditions for loans. This approach covers the whole range
of technically feasible market options, and is regularly revised to increase the required
energy efficiency standards.
Preferential loans with low-interest rates for energy efficiency can be combined with loans
for a new heating system based on renewable energies. Information-based programmes
complement the policy package, including the mandatory energy performance certificate
for buildings, and the targeted promotion of jobs and expertise related to energy efficiency.
Various information and trust-building measures for homeowners, tenants, experts, and the
construction industry support knowledge exchange and provide security for stakeholders in
the market.
The German energy efficient building programme has had a positive impact on energy
consumption, regional value chains, and investment dynamics in the sector. The
incremental introduction and tightening of regulations, accompanied by research and model
projects, have led to substantial reductions in primary energy consumption over time.
Source: Kemp, R. and Never, B., “Developing Green Technologies and Phasing Them In”
in PAGE, Green Industrial Policy: Concept, Policies, Country Experiences (2017) UNEP
and
DIE,
pp.
87-101.
https://www.unpage.org/files/public/green_industrial_policy_book_aw_web.pdf
4
Market-based instruments
Market-based or economic instruments are designed to price the use of environmental resources
and the emission of pollutants. Such instruments incorporate the “hidden” costs of production and
consumption in a cost-effective way, and represent an effective means by which to signal
environmental costs while leaving it to competitive market forces to find the most efficient
technological and organisational solutions. Some examples include taxes, charges, subsidies,
incentives and tradable permits, and liability and compensation schemes, while they may also extend
to environmental fiscal reform. This entails the removal of support or subsidies that are harmful to
the environment, such as tax exemptions for kerosene or subsidies for coal.
5
Market-based instruments can be employed to achieve a range of policy objectives, which can be
broken down into three broad categories:
•
Benefitting the environment
•
Raising fiscal revenues
•
Increasing fiscal efficiency and competitiveness
In terms of the developing country context, the prevailing renewable energy-related policies in SubSaharan African countries are fiscal incentives. These include tax reductions, public investments,
low-interest loans, and grants. Tax reductions – the most widespread incentive – require no additional
budget allocation (but do imply a budget loss), fewer administrative procedures, and minimal
regulatory supervision compared to other support policies [3].
More broadly, it has been argued that political economy constraints in developing countries are likely
to keep carbon and other pricing measures at a low level. A high incidence of market failures has
instead led to these countries adopting a greater number of non-price instruments (e.g. regulations)
than in developed countries. Such non-price instruments and infrastructure programs are favoured
as the most effective tools for achieving these objectives within developing countries, as they are
seen as being more credible than any long-term carbon price-signal [4].
Success factors for implementing economic or market-based instruments (MBIs):
Knowledge: Agencies responsible for implementing MBIs must have the technical knowledge
necessary to formulate and implement these instruments. At the same time, polluters must
possess the knowledge necessary for them to respond appropriately.
Good governance: Legal structures and frameworks must define property rights adequately, and
establish an authority to implement and enforce these.
Competitive markets: If firms are operating under soft budget constraints, they will not respond
as effectively to fiscal incentives.
Financial and administrative capacity: Agencies implementing MBIs must have the capacity to
initiate, monitor and enforce fiscal programmes.
Flexibility in response: The private sector and individuals should have freedom of choice in how
they are to meet the requirements under the MBI.
Source: Sharp, B., “Institutions and Decision Making for Sustainable Development” (2002) New
Zealand Treasury Working Paper 02/20, as cited in UNIDO, Green Industry: Policies for
Supporting Green Industry (2011) p. 67.
Environmental taxes and charges
Environmental taxes may operate within discharge limitations in order to make the polluting firm pay
for the discharges from its facility, even though they may be within regulatory limits. In this way, taxes
6
help to ensure that prices reflect the negative environmental impacts and costs of various products
and processes that are not included in the market price. At the same time, placing a cost on the
discharge of wastes and emissions creates an incentive for the producer to become more efficient,
and to reduce the intensity of their resource use and pollution [2].
Material input taxes can also be an important tool for increasing resource efficiency [5]. Such taxes
are a means of encouraging the more efficient use of resources, as well as fostering eco-innovations
to develop more material efficient production technologies and less material-intensive products.
Naturally, these have to be designed in a careful manner to ensure that they have the desired effect
and do not instead lead to undesired resource substitutions. Emissions into the atmosphere, for
instance, should ideally be charged at the same level in all countries because they are not confined
to a specific location or country. The proceeds from such taxes can then be used to cross-subsidise
the damage mitigation required as a result of adverse environmental impacts [2].
Examples of natural gravel tax
Material input taxes have been introduced in a number of countries – including Sweden,
Latvia, the United Kingdom, and Estonia – for the extraction of sand and gravel. The taxes
are charged either per weight or by the volume of the extracted material. Sweden adopted
its sand and gravel law in 1996, and in 2013 the tax generated SEK 146 million
(approximately USD 22 million) in fiscal revenue for the government. The price of the tax is
continuously monitored to ensure that it reflects an appropriate signal, with the Swedish
Government increasing the price from 13 SEK to 15 SEK per ton in 2014.
Source: PAGE, Practitioner’s Guide to Strategic Green Industrial Policy (2016) p. 82.
Example of a pesticides tax in the agricultural sector in Denmark
Effective as of July 1st 2013, Denmark’s pesticide tax is paid according to the significance
of the impacts that a pesticide has on health, nature, and groundwater. The pesticides with
the highest environmental and health impacts are the most heavily taxed, creating a strong
economic incentive to use those pesticides with the lowest footprints.
Industry response to the tax:
The Danish Food and Agricultural Council (Association of Farmers and Food Industry) were
pleased that the new tax was to be based on environmental and health impacts, and not on
consumption, and thought it was positive that those pesticides with the highest impacts
would be taxed the most heavily. They also emphasised the usefulness of having an
indicator for monitoring pesticide impacts, in order to make it easier for farmers and industry
to choose the pesticides that have the lowest footprints. However, the food industry
expressed concern that some crops would suffer as a result of the new taxes, and it was
also argued that the increased taxes could damage the industry’s competitiveness abroad,
potentially leading to a loss of jobs.
7
Source: The Danish Ecological Council, “Fact sheet: Tax on Pesticides.” Green Budget
Europe. https://green-budget.eu/wp-content/uploads/Tax-on-Pesticides_FINAL.pdf.
Tradable permits
Tradable permits have attracted growing attention in recent years as either a supplement or an
alternative to environmental taxes. When designing an emissions trading system, two key variables
relate to a) whether the authorities set an upper limit (cap) on the total amount of a substance (e.g.
CO2) that can be emitted; and b) how the permits for emitting pollutants are initially to be allocated
to the various enterprises involved. Once a tradable permit has been established, enterprises are
then free to buy and sell permits among themselves, facilitating greater economy-wide costeffectiveness and allowing greater scope for technological innovation. The EU Emissions Trading
Scheme represents one such example of a cap and trade system that is designed to reduce
greenhouse emissions from industry sources [2].
Pricing
Pricing influences spending and investment behaviour and is a powerful tool for determining patterns
of economic growth. Market prices do not usually reflect ecological costs, so while decisions made
on the basis of market prices may be economically efficient, they do not always generate positive
environmental outcomes. Policies should therefore be aimed at increasing the prices for raw
materials and energy in a way that accounts for the external environmental and social costs related
to resource use [2].
Environmentally-motivated subsidies
Subsidies are frequently used in policymaking to achieve an objective, such as stimulating
investment in green production technologies, when this will have positive adoption spillovers. They
can also complement the use of other market-based instruments, such as pollution taxes. Subsidy
support can come in many different forms, including through tax provisions, loan guarantees, and
charging below the cost price for public services, such as water, waste, and wastewater collection.
However, subsidies can also generate inefficiencies and negative environmental effects, and should
therefore be designed and applied with care. If not time-bound, subsidies can become “locked-in,” along
with the (potentially inefficient) practices or technologies that they support. At the same time, providing
subsidies to encourage compliance with direct regulations can result in significant economic distortions,
and induce strategic behaviour among enterprises [6].
To this end, environmentally-motivated subsidies are deemed not to violate the polluter-pays principle
when:
•
•
They do not introduce significant distortions in international trade and investment
They are limited to sectors which would otherwise have difficulties complying with environmental
requirements
8
•
They are limited to a well-defined transition period, and adapted too socio-economic problems
associated with the implementation of a country’s environmental policy [2].
Special Fund for Energy Efficiency in SMEs
Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) face multiple barriers to initiating energy
efficiency measures. Most SMEs lack the necessary technical knowledge to identify
efficiency opportunities, as well as the options available to them to take advantage of these,
including having the capacity to finance the adoption of energy-saving measures. As a
result, in 2008 the German Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy (BMWi) –
together with KfW, the public bank – established the “Special Fund for Energy Efficiency in
SMEs” to tackle both the knowledge and financial barriers that such companies face. The
programme has two components. First, it provides grants to SMEs to obtain advice and
consultancy services regarding potential energy efficiency opportunities. Second, it offers
low-interest loans to SMEs for investment in energy-saving measures. Overall, the
programme represents an effective tool in supporting the energy efficiency efforts of SMEs
in Germany.
Source: IEA, “Special Fund for Energy Efficiency in SMEs”
https://www.iea.org/policies/1769-special-fund-for-energy-efficiency-in-smes.
5
(2017).
Voluntary and informational instruments
Voluntary and informational instruments can be used to set more ambitious goals than regulations
and, at the same time, entail less administrative costs. Today, there are a range of voluntary and
informational instruments that can be employed by governments, business, and civil society to inter
alia raise awareness about sustainability issues, incentivise more sustainable behaviour, and
stimulate sustainable product and business development.
In particular, information-based instruments can promote a wide range of activities and services,
including environmental data collection and dissemination, development of indicators, environmental
valuation, energy audits, education and training, eco-labelling or certification schemes, and public
disclosure of enterprises’ environmental performance. Importantly, industry groups and civil society
have also been active partners in the promotion and use of such tools. While voluntary and
informational instruments are not exclusively the domain of industry, this represents a notable
contrast to the traditional “command-and-control” types of regulation.
9
In terms of environmental management and energy use, the ISO14000 and ISO50001 standards
have become important management tools for manufacturing enterprises that wish to green their
existing industrial processes. By adopting these standards, companies can enhance buyer-supplier
relationships while improving industrial competitiveness. They can also be employed as stand-alone
activities, or included in a package of programmes for subsectors or SMEs.
The Indian Green Building Council’s Green New Buildings Rating
System
The Green New Buildings rating system is a pertinent example of the non-regulatory options
that may be employed to support a green industry. In India, the Green Building Council
introduced the measurable ratings programme tool to aid and incentivise property
developers to apply green concepts, and to reduce negative environmental impacts beyond
those that are prescribed by law.
Different levels of green building certification are awarded based on the credits earned.
Certification levels range from “good practice” to “national excellence,” and finally to “global
leadership.”
Environment Management Systems (EMSs)
Environment Management Systems (EMSs) are another example of a voluntary measure
that can be used by both government and businesses to achieve improved environmental
outcomes, while at the same time helping companies to comply with environmental
regulations. EMSs are a type of management system which allow for external assessments
to be made against a common standard.
Source: PAGE, Practitioner’s Guide to Strategic Green Industrial Policy (2016) p. 82.
In the context of the transition towards a green economy, there has now also been a shift from the sale
of products to the sale of services. Tools such as chemical leasing (see below) fall into this category.
Ideally, such tools are combined with other measures to form more powerful packages for greening
industry.
Chemical leasing
Chemical leasing is a service-oriented business model that shifts the focus from increasing
the sales volume of chemicals towards a value-added approach. Under a chemical leasing
business model, the producer primarily sells the functions performed by the chemical, with
functional units forming the main basis for payment. Within such models, the responsibility
of the producer – now a service provider – is extended, and may include management of
the entire life cycle. Chemical leasing aims at promoting the efficient use of chemicals while
10
reducing the risks that they pose to the environment and human health. To this end, it
improves the economic and environmental performance of participating companies, and
also enhances their access to new markets. Key elements that have been identified from
successful chemical leasing business models include proper benefit sharing, high quality
standards, and mutual trust between participating companies.
Source: UNIDO, “Chemical Leasing” (n.d.) https://www.unido.org/our-focus-safeguardingenvironment-resource-efficient-and-low-carbon-industrial-production/chemical-leasing.
Pause to reflect
Participatory activity:
Identify and elaborate some of the advantages and disadvantages of each
of the policy categories and individual policy instruments.
Read:
Schlegelmilch, K., Eichel, H. and Pegels, A., “Pricing Environmental
Resources and Pollutants and the Competitiveness of National Industries”
in PAGE, Green Industrial Policy: Concept, Policies, Country Experiences
(2017) UNEP and DIE, pp. 103-116.
In the context of Denmark’s Pesticide Tax, how would you respond to and
address the concerns expressed by industry stakeholders? What
recommendations would you have for the Danish policymakers that
developed this tax?
6
A mixture of instruments
The optimal choice of policy instruments will largely depend on local and national conditions [7]. Today,
it is becoming increasingly common for governments to apply a mixture of policies and approaches
(through, for example, public-private platforms) to address increasingly complex and interrelated policy
challenges. This trend is in line with the recognition that no single instrument alone can effectively
promote the greening of industries, and is supported by innovation policy literature which emphasises
that a policy mix is particularly relevant for sustainable industrial transitions “that require joined-up
interventions from different policy domains” [7]. An increasing number of countries, including Peru,
Mexico, Denmark, Germany, and Portugal, are now adopting this practice [8]. The table below provides
an example from Denmark in the context of a circular economy.
11
Table 1. Example of policy instruments and tools currently being employed in Denmark to promote
circularity
Policy intervention types
Education, information &
awareness
Examples of existing policy interventions
•
Consumer information campaigns
•
Green industrial symbiosis programme
•
Four new partnerships (food, textile, construction, and
packaging) as part of the Danish waste prevention strategy
•
‘Genbyg Skive’ pilot project to re-use building materials in
order to create business opportunities and reduce waste
•
Fund for Green Business Development to support innovation
and new business models
•
Government strategy on intelligent public procurement
contains initiatives to support circular procurement practices
•
Strategy on waste prevention also contains an initiative to
develop guidelines for circular public procurement
Collaboration platforms
Business support
schemes
Public procurement &
infrastructure
•
Ambitious energy efficiency and GHG emission targets
•
Ambitious targets for recycling/incineration/landfill to
promote recycling and waste prevention (updated every six
years)
•
Taskforce for increased resource efficiency to review existing
regulations affecting circular economy practices
•
Taxes on extraction and import of raw materials, vehicle
registration and water supply
•
High and incrementally increased taxes on
incineration/landfill to promote recycling and waste
prevention
•
Highest energy taxes in Europe and CO2 taxes
•
Tax cuts designed to promote use of low carbon energy
Regulatory frameworks
Fiscal/economic
frameworks
Source: Based on Ellen MacArthur Foundation, Delivering the Circular Economy: A Toolkit for
Policymakers (2015) p. 46.
12
It is important that governments have the optimal mix of policy instruments in place, and that these are
supported by national strategies and integrated policy framework(s). Indeed, “finding the right policy mix
for a given challenge is strongly conditioned by the governance context in which individual policies
emerge and evolve over time” [7].
While a particular type of policy instrument – or mix of instruments – may appear appropriate on paper,
this does not always necessarily translate into public acceptance or enforceability. For example, a
particular instrument may produce results that are most consistent with the objectives of green industry,
but at the same time face public resistance or pushback from businesses if the policy is perceived to be
costly to implement. In some cases, undue influence may also be brought to bear by a limited number
of parties. A number of policy options should therefore be drawn in order to address possible uncertainty.
In most cases, policy mixes will need to respond to different challenges simultaneously. A green
industrial policy may need to both reward and penalise industries, while at the same time supporting
businesses through collective incentives. Doing so may require adopting a combination of “soft” and
“hard” policy measures. For example, the introduction of an environmental tax to stimulate resource
efficiency can only be effective if producers also have access to the financial, technological, and
knowledge resources necessary to change business behaviour in response.
Guiding considerations for selecting effective policy instrument mixes:
Flexibility: Instrument mixes should be constructed in an economically efficient manner, which
provides flexibility and does not stifle innovation. This can be achieved by setting long-term targets
that facilitate long-term investment decisions by both businesses and consumers (e.g. more
efficient processing technologies).
Combining instruments: Combining information-based instruments (e.g. labels) with measures
that directly target the environmental externality (e.g. tax/regulation) can enhance the
effectiveness of both instruments.
Avoid instrument overlap: While policy combinations can be beneficial or mutually reinforcing
(e.g. taxes and labelling schemes), overlap between some types of instruments (e.g. taxes and
product standards) can impede the proper working of the instruments involved, or generate
redundancies and unnecessary administration costs. One such example relates to the
overlapping objectives between extended producer responsibility obligations on the packaging
industry for packaging waste, and the statutory recycling targets set for local authorities.
Remove harmful subsidies: The effectiveness of a given instrument mix will be tempered if
subsidies are being given to ‘neighbouring’ sectors of the economy, and particularly where these
sectors are major contributors to the environmental problem in question. For instance, the
granting of agricultural subsidies can limit the effectiveness of policies designed to control the
extraction and quality of water.
Broad application: Instrument mixes should be applied as broadly as possible, covering all
relevant sectors of the economy as well as all countries. For “multi-aspect” environmental issues,
policymakers should combine instruments that limit the total amounts of pollution to be released
13
or emitted (e.g. performance standard) with instruments that address the way in which a certain
product can be used (e.g. technology standard).
Avoid transferring problems: It is important that policy mixes avoid transferring environmental
problems between different media (e.g. limiting the leakage of pollutants from waste landfills into
groundwater can result in an increase in air pollution from waste incinerators and compost plants).
Policy design: Policy mixes should be formulated in a way that encourages preventive rather
than end-of-pipe solutions.
Source: UNIDO, Green Industry: Policies for Supporting Green Industry (2011) p. 66. Citing
OECD, “OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030” (2008).
Finally, consideration of the potential costs and benefits of a policy mix is important. While the costs of
financial subsidies can be estimated easily, costs arising within enterprises and public administrations
that are subject to different policy instruments can be difficult to accurately quantify [9].
Recommended reading
Magro, E. and Wilson, J. R., “Policy-mix Evaluation: Governance Challenges from New Placebased Innovation Policies” (2019) 48(10) Research Policy.
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0048733318301550
14
Trencher, G. and van der Heijden, J., “Instrument Interactions and Relationships in Policy Mixes:
Achieving Complementarity in Building Energy Efficiency Policies in New York, Sydney and
Tokyo (2019) 54 Energy Research & Social Science 34-45.
https://www.researchgate.net/publication/331821298_Instrument_interactions_and_relationships
_in_policy_mixes_Achieving_complementarity_in_building_energy_efficiency_policies_in_New_
York_Sydney_and_Tokyo
OECD, “OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030” (2008). https://www.oecd.org/env/indicatorsmodelling-outlooks/40200582.pdf
7
Addressing market failures
As discussed in Modules 1 and 2, one of the key features of green industrial policy is that it is typically
designed to correct so-called “market failures”. For each of the five policy domains that were identified
in Module 3, the table below outlines the wide range of tools, measures, or instruments that can be used
to address market failures within these. The measures and instruments fall within the three broad policy
instrument categories that have been explored in this Module (command-and-control, market-based,
and voluntary/informational). It should be emphasized that not all of the measures, instruments and
indeed policy domains will be relevant for each country, and nor are the lists in the table intended to be
exhaustive. Indeed, the choice of domain, and the instrument or measure to be employed, will be based
on each country's respective idiosyncratic needs, nature of problems, level of industrialization, and
development goals.
Table 2. Policy instruments for addressing market failures
Policy domain
Intervention tools/measure/instrument to address market failures
Product
Import tariffs, export subsidies, subsidy reforms, tax credits, investment/FDI
incentives, green procurement policy, export market information or trade
fairs, linkage programmes, FDI country marketing, investment promotion
agencies
Labour
Wage tax credits/subsidies, training grants, training institutes, skills councils
Capital
Direct credit, interest rate subsidies, loan guarantees, development bank
lending, finance targeting infrastructure improvements
Land
Subsidised rental, EPZs, factory shells, infrastructure, legislative change,
incubator programmes
Technology
Technology transfer support, technology extension programmes
Source: PAGE, Practitioner’s Guide to Strategic Green Industrial Policy (2016) p. 80.
Finally, once the appropriate policy domain and policy measure or instrument(s) has been identified,
policymakers may encounter issues while implementing these. Where possible, such issues should be
identified beforehand. A policy selection matrix (PSM) can be employed for this purpose. A PSM
identifies the results associated with employing different types of policy instruments under a variety of
different policy conditions. The table below (on page 17) presents an example of a PSM in the context
of a green industrial policy formulation.
8
Conclusion
A range of policy instruments can be adopted as part of a green industrial policy to achieve
transformational change. These instruments are continually evolving: countries adapt and refine
their use according to past experiences, learn lessons in the process, and manage interactions
between different tools and measures. Command-and-control regulation, provided it is strictly
enforced, has a strong steering impulse. The steering impulse of voluntary/informational
instruments is soft, while market-based instruments lie somewhere in between – depending on the
scale of market manipulation, and the responsiveness (i.e. elasticity) of supply and demand curves.
The process of green industrialization is a complex undertaking, and calls for a holistic approach to
policymaking across economic, social, and environmental sectors. It is therefore fundamental that
governments employ instruments from each policy category, as part of a coordinated and strategic
15
policy mix. The specific design of this mix will be determined by the environmental issue to be
addressed, and on the specific circumstances of that country, including its stage of industrialization,
and local conditions and priorities.
16
Implementation
Issue
Command-andcontrol
instruments
Policy
management
cababilities
Regulation is
useful if
compliance is
observable, the
number of
regulated agents
is small, and
enforcement can
be safeguarded.
Less technical
capacity required
Small number of
polluters
Can be the most
effective
instrument when
the number of
polluters is small
Individual
negotiation with
market players
entails risks
Rent seeking
Market-based instruments
Taxes/Charges
Deposit
Subsidies
refund
schemes
The political aspects of monitoring and enforcement need
attention, as corruption complicates the implementation of
market-based policies. Subsidies may be subject to
lobbying, and information on their appropriate level may be
obtained by competitive processes, such as the public
tendering of renewable energy feed-in tariffs. “Sunset
clauses” should therefore be introduced and
communicated from the beginning
Smaller numbers of stakeholders/actors are able to
coordinate more easily and thus exert pressure on
policymakers to achieve favourable design for marketbased instruments
Create stakeholder
opposition
Has good
potential to
address rent
seeking
May trigger rentseeking and
related wasteful
activities.
Cap-and-Trade
Possible if the
number of polluters
is sufficient and
pollution sources
can be monitored.
However, it requires
a higher technical
capacity base.
Regulatory
measures may
therefore be
preferable if
technical capacity is
low
There is a risk of
price manipulation
when the number of
market participants
is too small
May be used as an
entry barrier, with
the risk that polluters
Voluntary/informational
instruments
Voluntary/informational
instruments are natural
starting points for
information disclosure
May be better for smaller
number of polluters
17
Carry a low risk of rentseeking.
Require “sunset
clauses” to
address such
behaviour
Inflation
Inflation complicates price-based policies
Distribution/
Poverty
Can have indirect
social and
distributive effects
when the costs of
regulation are
passed onto the
consumer
The regressive effects
of taxes can be
mitigated by revenue
use. Charges may be
more politically
appealing
May provide
people living
in poverty with
income
opportunities
Social and
distributional
effects depend
on who receives
and who pays
for the subsidies
Competitiveness
in small, open
economy
Global
coordination or
compensation of
taxpayers is
needed if global
competition is
strong
Global coordination or
compensation of
taxpayers is needed if
global competition is
strong
May be
suitable in a
small, open
economy
Compatibility
with
international
trade law needs
to be considered
(please see
Module 5 for
further
information)
will lobby for free
permits
Unaffected by
inflation
Tradable permits are
popular with
polluters if allocated
freely, but they can
lead to price
changes for
consumers (e.g.
energy prices)
Cap-and-trade
instruments may be
integrated into the
framework of
international treaties
(e.g. Kyoto Protocol
to the UNFCCC)
Unlikely to have negative
social or distributive effects
Can increase access to
environmentally-conscious
export markets if standards
are adhered to
Source: Table is adapted from PAGE, Practitioner’s Guide to Strategic Green Industrial Policy (2016) p. 83. Based on Sterner, T. and Coria, J., Policy
Instruments for Environmental and Natural Resource Management (2nd edn., Routledge 2012) pp. 256-257.
18
References
[1] UNIDO, “A Shift in the Production Paradigm” (2019) Making It Magazine. An
interview with Manuel Albaladejo. Retrieved from:
https://www.makingitmagazine.net/?p=10886.
[2] UNIDO, Green Industry: Policies for Supporting Green Industry (2011) p. 72.
Citing UNEP/Wuppertal Institute Collaborating Centre on Sustainable
Consumption and Production (CSCP), Wuppertal Institute for Environment,
Climate, Energy GmbH and GTZ, Policy Instruments for Resource Efficiency:
Towards Sustainable Consumption and Production (2006).
[3] Luken, R. A. and Clarence-Smith, E., “Green Industrialization in Sub-Saharan
Africa: A Guide for Policy Makers” (2019) UONGOZI Institute.
[4] Finon, D., “Carbon Policy in Developing Countries: Giving Priority to Non-Price
Instruments” (2019) 132 Energy Policy 38-43.
[5] PAGE, Practitioner’s Guide to Strategic Green Industrial Policy (2016) p. 82.
Citing Behrens, A. et al, “The Material Basis of the Global Economy: Implications
for Sustainable Resource Use Policies in North and South” (2005). Retrieved from:
https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/46a7/1570b2582e270e64fc58d891b61eb653e0a1
.pdf?_ga=2.44289956.1882134927.1590575340-943342942.1590575340.
[6] OECD. OECD Environmental Outlook to 2030 (2008). OECD, Paris.
[7] Magro, E. and Wilson, J. R., “Policy-mix Evaluation: Governance Challenges
from New Place-based Innovation Policies” (2019) 48(10) Research Policy.
[8] Ellen MacArthur Foundation, Delivering the Circular Economy: A Toolkit for
Policymakers (2015). Retrieved from:
https://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/assets/downloads/government/EllenMa
cArthurFoundation_Policymakers-Toolkit.pdf.
[9] UNEP/Wuppertal Institute Collaborating Centre on Sustainable Consumption
and Production (CSCP), Wuppertal Institute for Environment, Climate, Energy
GmbH and GTZ, Policy Instruments for Resource Efficiency: Towards Sustainable
Consumption and Production (2006).
19
Descargar