Journal of Development Economics 5 (1978) 107423. 0 North-Holland Publishing lCompaw THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF ARMAGEDDON: CHILE, 1970-1973 David LEH MANN* Cambridge University, Cambridge, England Received April 1977, revised version received November 15’77 1. The programme The election of Allende, supported by a coalition called Popular lrnity (UP.), in September 1970 was a product of divisions in the Chilean ruling class. Although ruling class groups, fractions and sectors had united with middle class and even some popular sectors to support Frei in 1964, landlords. big business and foreign capital had been frightened by his mild reformism ; they were furthermore irritated by his exclusion of all but the members of his own Christian Democrat Party and a fen* ‘independents’ from a government elected with their support. In 1970, therefore, they supported ex-President Jorge Alessandri’s candidature, provoked a three-way contest and allowed Allende to scrape home with only 37% of the vote. Popular Unity was a coalition which sollght to represen: rural and urban workers, peasants, and some middle classes. The dominance within the coali lion of the Communists and Socialists ensured that it would be very different from superficially similar Popular Fronts formed in the 1930s in Europe, and in 1938 in Chile, in which parties of the working class had taken a subordinate position. The one experience it did recall, though few cared to point this out, was that of Spain, immediately before the Civil War. The exphcit objective, expressed in formal statements such as the painfully elaborated Programa Basico de Gobierno, was not revolution, but revolutionary changes: ‘a replacement of the present economic structure, doing away with foreign and national monopoly capital and the latifundio in order to initiate the construction of Socialism.’ Socialism was a prospect in the distant future for the Communist Party, but a more immediate one for the dominant factions in the Solz’alist Party. Nevertheless the policies of the Frei and Al!:nde governments differed more in degree than in kind; behind them lay the same interpretation of Chilean development. of the structural *The author wishes to thank Sergio Bitar f.x drawing his attention to crucial weaknesses in the argument of an e;lslier draft. Remaining weaknesses are, c f coLx+sc,his own respmsibiiity. A 108 D. Lehmann, Chile, 1970-1973 pr&l~ms it had produced in the past and would encounter in the future. Both programmes stated that the existing income distribution in the society was a major obstacle both. to raising living standards and to economic growth, drawing from this the conclusion that by changing the structure of demand a new dynamism could be infused into the economy. This strategy had grown out of the ‘structuralist’ thesis, which had emerged in the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America since the 1950s and in various writings on the inflationary process in Chile.’ Both the U.P. and the Christian Democrat programme were based on the assumption that the unequal distribution of income prevailing in Chilean society constituted an obstacle to growth of any kind, that the unequal distribution of land in the agricultural sector was as much a cause of inflation as was monetary policy; both programmes allowed a role for domestic and foreign capital in the development process, albeit subject to government contr$ and with noticeable differences in emphasis. One fundamental difference was to be found in policy towards the copper companies: the Christian Democrats sought joint ventures (first ‘Chileanization’, later negotiated nationalization with compensation), a concept now practised all over the world, but first applied in Chile in 1965; U.P. sought total nationalization with compensation but added a deduction from compensation of ‘excess profits’ - a notion which was anathema to the international business community but which found unanimous support in the Chilean Congress, where U.P. was a minority. Yet U.P. did not want to break off relations completely vfith either domestic non-monopoly capital or foreign capital, and hoped to harness them to a new pattern of devek>pment &rough joint ventures, turnkey projects and the like, and through the division of the economy into social (state), private and mixed sectors. A further diffesence lay in diplomacy; Flrei had re-established commercial and diplomatic relati.lns with the People’s Democracies of Eastern Europe and with the Soviet Union, but drew the line at Cuba - timidly bat innovatively establishing commercial relations with the ‘4Jand in the latter years of his government. The restoration of full diplomatic relations with People’s China and, above all, with Cuba in the early months of the Allende government was thus a continuation of Frei’s policy, although symbolically it signified an affront to the United States. A crucial, and .:nnflictive, difference between the U.P. programme and the platform on which the Cristian Democrats had fought in 1964 concerned the nationalization of nl anufacturing industries. Frei and his party had spoken mildly of ‘part.icipatian’, ‘co-management’, profit-sharing and workers’ ,Jwner- ‘See Osvaldo Sunkei: ‘:La Inflation Chilena: un enfoque heterodox,n’, Ei Trimestre Ecunolnico, 100, Oct.-&c. 1958; Nicholas Kaldor: ‘Froblemas Economicos de Chile’, ibid., 102, April-June 1959, an.d a summary in Joseph Guunwald: ‘The “StructB~alist” School on Price Stabilization nnd Economic Development: The Chilean Case’, in Allot Hirschnan (ed.): Latin American Is,suess:Essays and Comaients, New Yolk, the Twentieth. Century Fund, 1961. D. Lehmann, Chile, 3570-1973 109 Ship;* the possibility that industrialists would be expropriated, as opposed to landlords, was not seriously considered. However, the Frei programme was ambiguous, and different party factions had emphasised different aspects of it during the campaign for Frei’s election. Of the slogan ‘Revolution in !Jberty’ some emphasised ‘Revolution’, others ‘Liberty’ - which in th2 Chile? ‘I context of 1964 meant keeping the left out of power. Later, in 1967. with the left faction in control of the party apparatus (though not of the go Jemment), a detailed ‘Political-Technical Report’ was produced by the Christian Democrats which sought to revive the ‘non-capitalist development path’ which Friel had once spoken of: the report proposed much stricter controls on private industry in the mining, capital goods and specific monopolistic sectors, sometimes recommending nationalization, sometimes merely tighter controls ‘. The report also proposed a gradual and experimental process whereby workers would participate in decision-making in their enterprises, although to&l workers’ control was postponed to a distant future. This was rejected, as was the report as a whole, by Frei and his faction, who soon recaptured control of the party apparatus. The internal divisions of the party came to a head when several of the authors of the report left the Christian Democratic Party in 1969 and formed a party of their own (the Movimiento de Action Popular Unitaria M.A.P.U.) which joined in the coalition of Communists, Socialists and, later, Radicals. It is not without interest to note that it was the M.A.P.U. intellectuals who drafted the original document on the basis of which the various parties of the left negotiated their Programme of Government. Where the Report of the Politico-Technical Commission hao been less a radicalized version of Frei’s original programme than a call to apply it consistently, the U.P. programme was a more radicalized version of the R.eport, in which controls were replaced by outright nationalization of the financiii system and of monopolies (only), while a harder line was adopted towards foreign capital. These subtleties of emphasis, however, reflected a morz profound and even dramatic debate in the Christian Democrat party was part of a far more concrete deba.te concerning electoral strategy in the forthcoming Presidential elections of 19X. Since 1968 the right-wing National Party had supported the candidature of ex-President Alessandri (Frei’s predecessor) in these elections, and it seemed inevitable that the Christian Democrats would lose them. Belief that Alessandri would v2n was widespread on account of the privileged access of ruling class interests to the media., No one took seriously the indications of electoral trends, which were that in a three-way contest the coalition of the left would stand a sporting chance, at the least. Since relations with the right were bad, the Christian Democrats had to choose between negotiating an alliance with the left %ee the Party’s Declaration of lDrincigles. 3The title of the report was ‘Proposiciones para una action politica en el pmiodo X967-70 de ma Via No Capitalista de Desarrollo’, published in the party journal dd!tica y Eyiritu. no. 303, October 1967. 110 D. Lehmann, Chile, 19704973 and losing power. For Frei, it was better to let Alessandri win rather than share power with Cortrmunists and Socialists, and he therefore tried to engineer a dual coup to discredit his main rival in the Christian Democrat Party and to put Alessandri in power. He imposed a strategy of ‘going it alone’ (the camino p~+o@o), and also forced a situation in which the rival, Radomiro Tomic, would be the candidate; this despite Tomic’s protestations that he would never accept nomination without an alhance with Communists and Socialists (under his leadership, and therefore unthinkable, for the left would have nothing to do with a former Ambassador to Washington) and despite the inevitability of his losing the election. Tomic fought and lost, but so did ,Alessandri. There was little in the U.P. programme which could be regarded as authentically or specifically marxist; pious talk about economic planning was little more threatening tbsn that heard in other underdeveloped clountries, and indeed Frei had already established a National Planning Office. The ‘dictatorship of the proletariat’ was totally absent. This might resemble the domestic programme of a Eurocommunist party, despite the very orthodox line of the Chilean C.P. in international affairs. The genealogy of the U.P.‘s initial programme lies in E.C.L.A. and in Christian Democratic thinking, and when the U.P. programme is compared to Tomic’s in 1970, the differences are slight indeed. The differences between the programmes of the two political forces should be seen more in terms of language than content: where the one speaks of a ‘communitarian society’ the other speaks of ‘revolutionary changes’ and ‘socialis:m’; where the one says ‘marginality’ the other sdys ‘exploitation’ ; on the whole the U.P.‘s language was closer to that of Christisrn Democrac:i than to marxism. Yet symbols are important in politics, and in the sophisticated world of Chilean politics, the significance of such subtle diflerences was not lost either on the elite or on the mass of the people. Both governments inherited an economy ir recession; both sought to pull it out of the recezslon by increasing wages, and in both 1965-67, and 1971 a ‘cushion’ of unused productive capacity and a favourable foreign exchange position permitted the miraculous and fugitive combination of growth, declining inflation, and dec::ning unemployment; but in both cases this process encountered an investment crisis and a foreign exchange crisis; and in both cases a more orthodox ‘mcnetarist’ policy was lhen app!ied to reduce demand through price inflation; th: difl’ering class bases of the respective governments explain the success of Frcrr and the failure of Allende in imposing the discipline of monetary orthodo?cy. When inflation began to mount after his expansionist and redistributive first vears, Frei applied an orthodox monetarist policy, managed from the central Bank by Jorge Cauas, later the architect of the Junta’s far more savage econoaic repression. Facing a crisis similar in structure, though far larger in ita proportions, th2 U.P. government was powerless. Some criiics said t’rlat U.P.‘s redistributive policy was a form of populism, and had little to do with socialism. To this, Pedro Vuskovic, Minister of Econo- D. Luhmann, Chile, 19704973 111 mic Affairs, replied npi*rely that the installation of ‘socialist relations of production’ in nationalized iuaustries was a guarantee of the Transition to socialism, and income redistribution was a prerequisite for the transition process4 The middle classes were optirristically seen as essentially progressive, and the whole programme was intended to harm only the interests of a very small minority of foreign and local monopoly capitalists. One Important theme in the U.P. period was the Communist Party’s repeated, desperate ;rnct impossible attempts to construct an alliance with the ‘middle sectors’. The programme then stated the coalition’s intention to fully nationalize the largest copper companies and all domestic and foreign monoF,,lies. Three ‘areas’ of property would be created : state, private and mixed owner ,hip sectors. Institutional changes involved the creation of a single-chamber Glngr:ss, and various administrative reforms in the hope of decentralising tht: pcnderous state machine and democratizing its administration. Repeatedly thl: programme refers to the organization of the people as a guarantee for its fuldilrrent. This idea harks back to the Christian Democratic ‘Revolution in Libcrt!’ and the ‘communitarian society’, now to become effective as a result of concomitant changes in the structural and institutional context. Apart from the usual intentions to raise living standerds, reduce the r-ate of inflation and improve social services and social security, the programme also emphasised the emergence of a new culture from ‘the struggle fcr fra;temity and against individualism, for the valorization of human work anal against its denigration . . .’ - again, a language reminiscent of the ‘Revolution in Liberty’. The provisions of Frei’s Agrarian Reform Law (in force since 1’167)were to be applied to the maximum. Ideally, the U.P. would have liked tc pass a new Law, but it did not have the necessary parliamentary majority ant1 meAnwhile the existing Law oEered very wide scope for expropriation. Like the Christian Democrat programme of 1964, the U.P. programme proclaimed the need for radical social change within the existing institutional framework, but income redistribution simply could not be accomplished on the scale envisaged by either government within the existing institutional order, even if the government had all the majorities it required. The Christian Democrats a party with a bourgeois leadership, a middle class membership a:ld a working class and peasant following - drew back well before reac,$ing the brink, whereas when eventually some of the U.P’s leaders wanted desperately to draw back they uould find their retreat cut off. The thre;it to the institutional c rder during both governments came from two sources: ,>ne, obviously. was the Army, hut there wars also the danger that the prospect of a redistribution of Income and power would provoke political mobilization on an unpreccdes?ted scale, ClnS.5 conflict in which institutions, not wages, were at stake, radically different from 4Centro de Estudio:; Socio-Economicos and Centro de Estudics de la Rea,idad Narional (CESO(CEREN): Trmsicion al Sclciaiisrno y Espcriencia Chilena, 1972. The refewncr is to Vuskovic’s intervention in a conference reported in this volume. 112 D.Lehmann, Chile, 1970~19513 the corporate type of class confXct to vlhich Chilean organizations were accustomed. ChiEe:anpoliGcs has long hinged on a large and flexible centre, and on the absence ol’ a thyeat to the gradually improving economic status cf the middle classes. The deepening political crisis fuelled and was fuelled by the polarization and disappearance of that centre, and the political activation of the threatened middle classes in the face of the heady process of popular mobilization. 5 The M.I.R.,6 in particular, and the Socialist leader Carlos _4ltamirano, as well as individuals such as Wegis Debray,’ announced the inevitability of a confrontation, and their analysis, if not their prescription, was more realistic. How would the people deal wifh the confrontation when it came? In general, the political parties of the left, accustomed to many years of parliamentary practioe, were not structurally capable of leading the people in extra-institutional situations, let alone in a miiitary conflict. The very apt slogan ‘Convertir cl gobierno en pode:r:’is almost umtrans;atable, referring to the aim of transforming an institultional authority restricted to one branch of the state machine into hegemonic power in civil society. But its achievement required a revolutionary party which was a.bsent. The substantive: difference,, then, lay less in the programme than in the determination to apply it, and above all in the radically different class composition of the fences which brought the respective governments to power. Frei, in his own right, did have at multi-class support base of capitalists, middle classes, workers and peasants, but he would never have been elected without the votes of the upper strata who:, in e:ntremis, gave him crucial last-minute support, on account of their fear that Allende v:ould win the 1964 election. Faced with crucial choices, he chose repression - economic in the monetarist policies of his later years, and political in his use of police and army against workers and squatters. In the years of expansion he was prepared to redistribute income or expropriate estates, for at that point these policies did not contradict the logic of the economic system. But when the pursuit of income distribution threatened to undermine the private control of industry, or when expropriation of estates begzrn to encounter hostiiity among commercial farmers and industrialists, the two processes wzrc respectively halted or slowed down. Frei’s commitment to law and order was stiff when. workers were on the streets or squ,atters illegally occupying land. But it was less stiff when commercial farmers blocked the Pan American highway. And t’here is some evidence that he turned a blind eye to the unsuccessful attempt to prevent Allende’s accession, which led to the murder of the Commander-in-Chief of the Army in late 1970. Under Frei, people died 5This noint is we:i made in Manuel A. Garreton and Tomas Moulian:Procesos y Bbques Santiago, PLACSO, 1977. Vhe Left Revolutirmary Movement. ‘Regis D&ray: Cmver,mtions with Alted, New Left Books, London, 1971. SW ~SO, for examlple, the declaratilon cf the M.I.R. published in Pmto Find, no. 114, September 29, 1970. Poiitkus x la Crisis chikna, 19704973, D. Lehmunn, Chile, 19704973 113 in repressive army and police actions in the mming town of El %alvadors, in Puerto Montt, and in the Santiago suburb of La Florida. Allende, on the other hand, had his only solid support in the urban’working class, with a substantial but not overwhelming - number of rural workers and peasants, and a m nority of the middle classes. He was lenient almost to a fault, anJ publicly apologized for the one incident which marred his government’s non-rzpreessive record at La Hermida, a Santiago shanty-town. Since his political co; .tzc1 of the repressive forces was partial and decreased as time went by, he cannot br held responsible either for their leniency towaros the para-mili!ary groups of the right, or ;‘x the abuse of the army’s right to search for arms when, during 1973, they used that right as an excuse to repress workers, peasants and government officials. Similarly, in economic policy, the U.P.‘s class base was manifest in the government’s inability to carry through consistently a monetarist retrenchment from mid-1972, after the redistributi;re efforts of 1571. The r:>tegration of the Chilean state machine in the capitalist system as a whole is manifested by this: by the maintenance of its centralization and autonomy when its repression is directed at workers and peasants, and by its disintegration aud the colonization of its agencies by forces arising in civil society when an attempt is made by the civilian executive to point its guns - real and metaphorical - in the opposite direction. Much depends on the ‘margin for manoeuvre’ offered by the economy as a whole, but it would appear that in a period of financial crisis in an economy heavily dependent on imports and foreign credits, the brunt of the burden of retrenchment cannot but fall on the working cla:;ses; an attempt to preserve gains in income distribution while retrenching implies making industries operate under totally new conditions which a.re likely to contradict the prevailing logic of capital accumulation - a redistribution which in a period of expansion could just fit into that logic. Yet the retrenchment is probably-in the knife-edge conditions of a primary commodity exporter on the periphery of the world economy - an inevitable consequence of an attempted income redistribution and its concomitant, monetary expansion. Political forces seeking to undertake a redistribution of income could learn this one lesson from the Chilean experience: to be on the safe side, plan for austerity, not for a consumption boom. This finds support in the experience of a long list of countries which have passed through and sustained an equalization of their economl~c structure: the Soviet Union, Cuba and Tanzania are obvious examples. In contradicting the ic,gic of capital accumulation, government finds itself forced to redirect radiahy th.: activities of the state, to ta.ke over direct, centralized control of production and final demand, and thus impose, under necessarily harsh conditions, a different logic of accumulation. If this different logic is unavailable, or if the ;!ower to impose it is not available, this hypothetical strategy is ir terrupted in mid-stream: the colonization of the state by the class forces of civil society which support or oppo!se the government, and which the governmeltlt cannot repress, will be expressed in the fragmentation of control over nomjnally nationalized industries and farms, subject to no single new rationality. “The accumulaL,,n process is thus reversed while forces disparately seeking an ill-defined “new order’ wrestle unequally with the laws of capitalist circulation: Chilean inflation was, in this period, no more than a reflection of that underlying battle. It may appear paradoxical that, despite the differences, I insist also on the similarities between Allende’s and Frei’s original programmes, and above all on the similarity between the interpretations of Chilean history on which ,hey were based. The explanation lies in their common assumptiou that Chilean income distribution was an obstacle to growth, and that therefore redistribution would not enter into contradiction eventually with economic cantinuity, that indeed it would improve the economy’s growth performance’ without upsetting the logic of capital accumulation.. U.P. presented many new measures, but not a new model, let slone a socialist model of accumulation. The coalition’s socialism operated at the level of mstitutions, not at that of the economic mechanism. 2, Economic policy Within a short time, the U.P. had passed to the olfensive on all fronts; on January 1, 1971 wage increases were awarded in such a way as to f’avour the lowest-paid workers in industry and agriculture, and many prices were held down. With 40 percent of industrial capacity apparently lying idle industrialists could respond to tne expansion of demand, although the structural bottlenecks which explained some underutilization of capacity continued to have their effects, as did the f:wtreme political uncertainty. As in 1965-67, when the Christian Democrats carried out a simila; programme, profits per unit of production may not have risen, but total profits presumably did. rise. During 1971 Gross National Product rose by 8 percent and industrial production by 15 percent. The share of wages in ldational Income rose to 59 percent, having stood at S1.7 percent on an average between 1960 and 1969.9 In the municipal elections of March 1971the U.P. won almost 50 percent of the vote:,” in contrast to the 37 percent it had won in the Presidential elections the previous Sep.. tember. During 1971 the complete and unanimous nationalization by Congress of foreign-owned or part-owned copper mines was achieved, and 130 important sThis is especially notable in the absurdly optimistic forecasts in U.P.‘s hastily assembled Economic Plan, which pruJected concurrent increases in i,ncome equality, GNP, employment and produciivity. For a critique see Alejandro Foxley and Oscar Muiioz: ‘Income Retlistribution, Economic Growth and Social Structure’, O.xford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, XXXVT, 1, February 1974. ‘ODEPLAN (Oflicina de Planificacibn National): Antecedentes sobre ei desarrollo Chileno, 19m-1970,1971, p. 43. ,“74 percent of registered voters participated in these elections. D. Lefimann, Chile, 19704973 115 enterprises passed either by purchase or by ‘intervention”’ into the hands of the State.” By July 1972, 3,278 farms had beer, affected by the agrarian reform process, in addition to the 1,,412 expropriated under Frei. The number of peasants benefitted by that time was of the order of 75,000 - rather more than 10 percent of the rural labour force, Nationalised industries were placed under the control of administrative councils on which workers’ representatives sat side by side with government appointees - the latter numbering one more than the former but not forming a homogeneous bloc. It was difficult to control seizures of industries, and even more so to limit wage increases. The government reached agreements with the C.U.T. (the Central Organization of the Trade Unions) in 1971 and 1!?72 at the national level, but the wage increases agreed were surpassed in almost all factories. r3 Wages were rising with particular speed in the nationalised industries, and the only imaginable way of limiting them would have been through rationing or massive inflation: this latter was to ct Jme, but only became a successful method of reducing demand after the putsch. By mid-1972, the Communist Party in particular, frightened of alienating the middle sectors., was advocating a policy of consolidatien, involving a slow-down in nationahsation, monetary restriction and an increasingly shrill attack on the ultra-left. The money supply increased by 113 percent in 1971; overall consumption increased by about I3 percent between 1970 and 1971 ;I4 the effect of demand generated among low-income groups on food products was disproportionate given income elasticities and price subsidies. Exchange rate policy permitted an unprecedented increase in food imports even at a time when world copper prices were declining aad world food prices were rising astronomically. Food imports, which had cost an average of 11.7 percent of export earnings in 196% 70, rose to 15.7 percent and 33.1 percent in 1971 and 1972; from $125 million per year in 1945-70 to $180 million in 1971 and $364 million in 1972; the prices of these imports rosle 8 percent in 1971 and 41 percent in 1972. Domestic food production, which had grown by 3.5 percent per annum in “This term refers to government take-over of the management of a factory or farm without actual take-over of ownership. It was possiblein virtue of a law decreed by the 100~fray Socialist Republic 1931-2. According to this legislation - which had lain dormant and forgotten on the statute books -the government could, in the case of social conflict or similar difficulty, ‘intervene’ in the ;lirm or farm c.,ncerned. 12The passing of many industries into rhe hands of the State was a haphazard affair in some cases: groups sometimes not controlled by the U.P. -and perhaps not control% by anyone - would create a faitaccompli by occupying a factory, for example, and more or less forcing the Ministry of Labour to ‘intervene’ simply in order to avoid lengthy halts in production. Thus a number of firms in tr,e Area de Propidd Social (State Sector) wer; not really ‘wanted’ in it, while some ninety large and important monopoiies were still in private hands, awaiting more conventional ConstiFutionaf procedures to be taken over - proceJurcs for which the necessary Congressional approval was not forthcoming. ‘Wages increased by about 50 percent in 1971 and about IO percent in 1972. 14Prper by Edgardo Hoto, Cambridge, 1977. 116 D. Lehmunn, Chile, 19704973 1965’10, grew by 4.7 percent in 1970-1, ;and 1.3 percent in 1971-2. Total agricultural production grew slightly more in 1970-72 bu5 in any case the figures conceal marked variations in certain crops and in livestock. Wine and grape production grew by some 30 percent in 1970-71, and crop production by 10.3 percent, while livestock barely increased at all, partly due to contraband exports in the south, to Argentina. If the ,eBect of the increase in wine and grape producti:on in 1970-71 is discounted, the increase for that yea.r is 2.9 percent.‘5 In 1971-2, cattle production declined, due perhaps to inflation, which encouraged farmers to keep cattle on the Ihoof, while livestock products such as eggs, chickens and pigs increased substantially. Thus total lives.uck production rose some 6.6 percent; but crop production fell by 4 percent (in spite of a 2.6 percent increase in area sown). Wheat declined 13 percent, maize 12 percent and sugar beets 14 percent. Thanks to ,the use of idle industrial capacity, to price control, and to agricultural imports, inflation in 1971 was much lower than in 1970 (22.1 percent compared to 54.9 percent). However, b:y the beginning of 1972 black markets, shortages and queues were beginning to appear, and inflation started its march up to three figures,. It is very difficult to understand the ratioma le bebind the policies of Vuskovic and his team. Of course, Frei had followed! a similar policy in 1965-66, but he had reimposed orthodoxy when a continuation of the redistributive process came into conflict with political stability. ‘Erskovic claimed that he sought to reactivate an economy depressed by Frei’s monetary orthodoxy by expanding demand and using up idle capacity, while at the same buying popularity for the g;.;vernment and support for further structural changes. That is one account. Airother, less charitable account might be that Vuskovic and his team knew the probable consecduences of th.eir actions, and were seeking to force the governxnent iut.0 I position where it would have to either impose orthodox,y anu ally with its enemies to do so, or else impose (another orthodoxy) central planning and r.a:tioning, and thereby risk a revolutionary confrontation. It should be added th.at the policy did not, as far as can be leen, have much efFect on overall income distribution, since it raised the incomes (>falmost all classas. These included the middle classes, some of which were eventually to be the warhorses .of the blourgeoisie in the counter-revolutionary movemerrt. Also, much of the purported idle capacity arose from bottlenecks in the economic system which could not be eliminated 0vernight.l’ The judgement one passes on Popular Unity’s, strategy as a 3whole must depend fundamentally on one’s evaluation of the economic policy (or, more ’ “Source: UNDO-FAO-ICIRA: .Diagnkfko de la Refirma Agraria Chikwa (Ndembre i’9ALJunio 1972), 1972. This report was co-ordinated by Solon Barraclough. It differs little in the eswxce of its tidings on production from reports put out by the Agricultural Econjomics IDepartment of the Catholic University at a simiku time. 160n bottlenecks see Edgardo Floto’s wpublished paper. On income distribution see Alejandoo Foxky and Oscar Mufioz, op. cit. D. Lehmann, Chile, 19704973 117 strictly, the incomes and financial policy) fc-llowed during the government’s first six months, because there is a strong argument for saying that as a result thereof the g0vernmen.t lost its initial freedom of manoeuvre, and that only afterwards did disaster become inevitable, Now suppose one believes, as I increasingly believe, that incomes policy in this period was controlled by EL particular group of technicians with no firrr party affiliation within the stete apparatus, who did not explain the probable consequences of their actions fully to the President and to the leaders of the various parties. Then it is possible to conclude that the strategy of structural change within the institutional order was nbt allowed to be tested in practice because the retreat essential to the maintenance of that orcler was cut off from the outset. Faced with a choice ‘between institutional collapse and the continiled pursuit of income distribution, %he policy of the dominant forces at Cabinet level (but not on the ground) was clear: retrenchment and consolidation. Vuskovic’s policy had made this impossible. If, on the other hand, one believes that the eccnomic policy followed in the early months was an inherent feature of the government’s strategy (even though it was not spelt out in the Programa de Gobierno), then clearly the strategy as a whole stands indicted, For the principal consequence of the policy was that the government lost control ; by generating high inflation (130 % in 1972) it generated high wage demands, especially in the nationalised and ‘intervtined” industries, and by holding food prices down and operating a very low exchange rate for wheat and even rnea::,it provoked such a pressure on the foreign exchange position that within little time a relatively comfortable position had been turned into a very uncomfortable one indeed.’ ’ Despite a barely spoken a.wareness of this problem, the government continued to try to use the existing institutions; indeed it had little choice,’ since the option of creating different ones was not open. Congress, in which the opposition parties had an ample majority, refused necessary legislation either to advnnce further on the road to socialism or to halt the process and ‘consolidate’. Rationing might have enabled a preservation, and indeed a reinforcement, of apparent gains in income distribution while ensuring that scarce food supplies reached the consumer, ‘but the opposition parties resolutely refused to allow anything of the sort. In any case, it was probably bureaucratically unfeasible on a large scale. In thecry, inflation could play the role of a ‘tax’ but it would ’ % his book Ablende’s Chile: the Political Econonly of the R,:w and Fall of Unidad Popular, Cambridge ‘UniversityPESS, 1976, Stefan de Vylder specificallystates that despite boycotts by traditional sources of aid and credit in the U.S. and in the IDB and IBRD, Popular Unit!, was able to find as much credit as previous Chilean g,overnments had found in Western and Eastern Europe The problem was the ‘bottomless’ den,and for imports in the economy. It is not uninterestin:,: to note that Eastern European countries were singularly unsympathetic to requests for cre& for current, consumption to buy cff the mIddIe classes. They were sympathetic to requests; for capital aid, but this was for long-term projects and few if any ever got off the ground. Thus the economic boycott cannot be blamed for very much, though the government could well have done without the dislocations it provoked. 118 D. Lehman, Chile, 1970-1973 only be eflective if it could be controlled in such a way as to channel resources into a centrally planned state sector’” -- and legislative facilities for this were most certainly not available. In practice, from Vuskovic’s removal in mid-1972 until the coup in September 1973, economic policy consisted of a series of attempts to return to fiscal orthodoxy and tcb reduce demand which could not achieve their aims. They could not achieve their aims because the government could not and would not complement them with the political repression which forms an essential part of the application of monetary orthodoxy in CI,sis siituations in peripheral economies. The opposition, after its first few months of disarray, was far from ‘loyal’. They conducted a highly sophisticated campaign of harrassment in parliament, in the streets, in the wild scare-mongering of the (CIA-financed) press. The CIA most probably finauced the lorry-drivers’ strikes,‘” and lhad connections with the para-military fascist groups which eventually operated with almost total impunity. It was a classic case of the application of the slogan once coined by Stalin: ‘th;: worse, the better’. The powerlessness of the authorities w3s, however, not only a result of dishonest opposition: the machinery of government itself was in a state of increasing disorganization. Jobs in the government apparatus had been allocated on a quota basis to the various parties in the coalition. With the exception of some particularly effective prc. *ammes - such as the improvement in health services, the distribution of free milk to small children, which led to a remarkable decline in infant mortality rates, and the expropriation of land - it was exceedingly di5icult to implement any policy at all. Individuals depended for their jobs on party patronage and not on bureaucratic hierarchy, and thus the possibility of applying one single policy was limited. Apparent unity at the Cabinet level concealed rivalries and deep disagreements at all levels between piarties and within the bureaucracy they had colonized. Similarly, a problem of authority arose in the relationship between the bureaucracy and its environmlent. :For example, the parties were not in a good position to exercise control in nationalized industries, even in the copper mines.20 In earlier crises, politicians had found ways of compounding their difhrences in the interests (ofthe preservation of institntlons. Conflict between the Executive and a Congress controlled by the opposition had after a!1 been the rule, not the exception, in rescent Chilean history. Now,, however, with every day that passeu, ‘*On the ro!e of inflation during a transition period, see E. Preobrazhensky: The New Clarendon Press, 1965. Krvnes once described inflation as ‘a: form of taxation which the public find hard to evade and even the weakest government can enforce wlhen it can enforce nothing else’. The trouble ir that a u*eak government cannot actually lay its hands on the tax in a systematic way. “Wl~y else wordd the spiralling descent, of tt : escudo’s black market exchange rate have been reversed durjng the strikes? ‘ONorman Gall: ‘Copper is the wage of Chiie’, Anrericun Universities Field .%q.trReport.~, Clkst Coast, South American Series, XIX, 3, August 1972. Economies. Oxford, .D. Lehmann, Chiie, 1970-1973 119 the re-establishment of stability on the basis of minimum consensus between even the C.P. and the C‘nristian Democrats become more and more remote. Every farm or factory legally expropriated or illegally and spontaneously seized raised the costs of a cleal for the government and reduced its benefits, in the short term, for the opposition. Every new seizure meant that much more repression in the event cf a deal, while offering the opposition Ihe opportunity and the temptation to arouse the fears of the middle classes. Class conflict therefore continued to develop in intensity beyond the scope of institutions, making a violent solution inevitable - a solutitin which could only be fascism or revolution.2i The Christian Democrats are today paying the price of their irredentism. It would be highly misleading to leave the story there, for, side by side with ir disorientated and fragmented government, remarkable movements grew up among the urban and rural proletariat and the peasantry which demonstrated a far clearer understanding of what W;LSat stake than did the leaders of the main left-wing political pasties. Unfortunately, these movements did not have the orcap;?ation or the leadership which might have enabled them to carry out a swcessful revolution. It is all too easy to blame these movements - the ‘extreme left’ as they are vulgarly known - for the failure of Popular Unity. They are better interpreted as a reaction by certain sections of the rural and urban proletariat and the peasantry to the weakness, indecisions and contradictions of a government which they fervently supported. 3. The rise of autonomous revolutionary movements The disconcerting feature of the process was that mass mobilisation was not a prerogative of the left. There came a point, perhaps with the prolonged lorry-drivers’ strike i.1 October 1572, when all formal political orgsnisatiorl; lost control of what w’as happening OR the ground, though some did choose, by their verbal violence, to encourage it, Even the Christian Democrats and rightwing Nacionales werf: having to follow movements initiated by lorrydrivers, shopkeepers, bus-drivers, entrepreneurs., doctors and other groups organised in gremios. 22 No doubt there was quite an effec:tive conspiratorial organisarion behind the upstart leaders of these organisations, but it was evidently successful in canalising the discontent of gro+VFW I_whose distrust of politician ; and political institutions affecl;ed the Christian Democrats and Nacionales ;.s well as the U.P. 21A,:~ndamentalerror of many ;ibera.lswho oppose the Pinochet regime is their implicit belief that a moderate solution was available. After 1971, it wasn’t. 22This word is a generic term for any kind of corporate interest group: thus in the past normal trade unions (sindica~os) also called themselves gremius. ?hc right appropriated the term an,i generalised ,its use in order to unde:line their claim to be without any political affiliations. 120 D. Lehmann, Chite, 19704973 On the left, there was an absence of co-ordination of extra-insti,tutional aci-ion (let ~ln?e co,+racyj, either from within the institutional parties, or from tha M.T.R., or frown any other source. During the electtiral campaign of 1970 Cornit& de Unidad Popular had been formed in workplaces and on street blocks, especially in urban areas; they were multi-party affairs, but operating In an electoral and oppositional context where it was not hard to maintain nnity. .After the election, these committees lost their momentum as parties, and their militants turned their energies to staffing the state machine, and trying to implement government policy. In contrast, during the succeeding years, the popular organisations w%cb grew up were increasingly independent of any political party, and of the MAR. as well, and they arose as much from conflicts with the State machine as from conflicts with capitalists. Th.ere may also be some substance in the hypothesis that the people who participated in these new forms of organisation were drawn from social categories which had not previously been signitlcantly involved in sustained organised political or corporate activity: unemployed rural workers, women, young workers. (Certainly, this phenomenon of ‘newness’ was very evident on the other side: the lorry-drivers seemed at fist to emerge from nowhere and the housewives of the middle class were remarkably active.) New organisations sprang up in nationalised or ‘intervened’ enterprises, and in the countryside in the shape of Peasant Councils (Consejos Cuntpesinos). Ih the towns, the homeless continued a movement of seizures of land which had. been going on throughout the sixties; with government, help in providing resources, new ca~npamentos were formed and some h;ad a high level of participation in inaernal organisations, covering health, education, the maintenance of public order and so 0n.l 3 Hn 1972 and 1973 autonomous ‘Comandos Comunales’ anid ‘Cordones Inldustriales’ were formed in industrial suburbs in Santiago, Conception and other towns. A high level of popular organisation was achieved to cope with the October 1972 lorry-drivers’ and shopkeepers”s strike, preventing the country from be:ing brought to a complete standstill, but after the strike was over things were ‘brought back to i?ormal’ amid much criticism from the M.I.R.. and :pome Socialists that the coalition was again renouncing a revolutionary form of organisation as it bad abandoned the Unidad Popular Committee:s. But as the class war developed wit.h renewed vigour after the March 1973 Congressional elections, these forms of popular organisation returned to the fray, seizing factories, carrying (out various forms of protest such as road blocks and strikes, and also trying to organize production. ‘“The best-known campamentos wete Nueva la Habana and Lo Hermida. But one’s vision this phenomenon is distorted betause the M.I.R. was adept at publicising its activities. An overview is to be found in Joaquin Duque and Ernest0 Pastrana: ‘La movilizaci6n reivindicativa en 10s se43ores popular~ en Chile, 19fi4-1972’, RevMa Latinoan~ericanade Ciencks So&&s, &amber 4,1972. D. Le~ann, Chile, 19704973 121 During the failed coup of June 197324 many factories were seized, but the government, especially t.he C.P., desperate to pacify the opposition, gave instructions to hand the factories back after the storm had, provisionally, passed. Another example of popular organisation was found in the Jzlntas de hzstecimien@ JJ Precios (Supply and Price Boards) set up in working class suburbs in order to channel goods at fixed (i.e. non-black-market) ,>riccs to these areas. They were administered by peop!c living in the suburbs, \+ith varying degrees of cooperation from the political parties of the left, and rece ved their supplies through a state marketing corporation This seems to have arisen as a popular initiative, and the government was able to cooperate er%ciently enough to make it work ts some extent, though I do not know whethera bal.anced evaluation is possible, All this activity represented a darger to the established parties of thl: left, especially the Communists who were incapable of guiding it and felt rhreatccec! by it: they were accustomed to students taking up revolutionary views, but no; to workers doing so. Jn the CommLnnist Party, all levels of organisation ~,vere closely tied to national directives, and there was little room for legitimate autonomous action at the level of the cell or Regional Committee. Although union activists in the party had some autonomy because they had an independent base of power, the evidence is thai they remained largeiy within the confines of conventional union acuvity: this had net troubIed the party - so long as it was a party of the opposition. 25 But organisations which uere capable cf dealing with ncgotiatlons for wages encountered many difficulties whet1 faced with the democratization of factory manager? -nt. Thus, in a number of nationalized or ‘intervened’ factories in the region of Conception after 1970, the same group might elect a pro4Z.P. leadership for their union, and an Administrative Council more sympathetic to the M.I.R. Many C.P. unionists did ignore the wage guidelines agreed by the government and the C.U.T. (the central Trade Union body dominated by the C.P.) in 1971 and 1972, while the M.i.2 operly encouraged their violation with enormous wage claims. The reaction of the Communists to the emergence of institutions of workers’ power independent both of the state and of the pa??y or trade union apparatus was to turn their backs on it, and conduct campai&ms against the extreme left and against irresponsible wage demands, calling upon the workers to recogni:;e that their most important role was in production.26 In a peGod when the issue 240r was it a dress rehear&? It was known as the ‘tancazo be-awe :‘l WAS I:.&ed out by a tank regiment. 2%ee Allan Angell: PO&tics and the Lobow Move.ment in Chik~, Lor dor, Ox ford University Frcss, 1972, pp. 148-151. *6See the important article by Odando hl’ilias, member of the Political 0,mmittee of the C.P., aod subsequently Minister of Finance, El S&lo, 5/6/72: ‘Revollrtionary participation is effective if it operates above all in the field of production and ~aages, s:~:ctly based on :I realistic economic plan which fixes very clear targets of increas.ed productivity and expanded reproduction and which has been discussed section by section, and drawn up democratically... ’ And on the role of unions: ‘We Communists must WEto it that there is a unitair. representation of the workers #andthat the trade unions carry out the r-ore important role.’ 122 D. Ldmmn, Chile,19704973 of power lay behind tb.at of pay, some sought to keep pay tlown while maintaining an institutional structure geared to the annual round of wage demands, while others sought to use a new structure of workers’ control in order to demand wage levels and regah (perquisites) which were fuelling inflation, and (more important) eating into the economy’s surplus.‘“’ The Socialist Party was a party of urban and rural caudillos, old-time social democrats, old-time trotskyites, and revolutionaries who had more in common with the M.P.R. and were often members of both parties. But the party did have a strong representation in the trade ucfon mov’ement,. The Secretary-General, Altamirano, had ever since 196’7espoused the position that revolution withcut violence was impossible, and ahhough he formally kept the party within &e U.P. coalition, he did little and perhaps could not do much, to keep his rank and file in line. Socialists operated without much central control, with the result that they were perhaps more active than the M.I,R. in encouraging indepe-rdent grass roots action - for the M.Y.R. did have a structure of command, and was aware of the dangers of adventurism. The Communist Party’s more strident attacks on the ultra-left were often directed at the (unnamed) Socialists rather than at the M.I.R., and Allende const.antly disassociated himself from this, his own, part~j, aligning himself with the C.P. Socialist Party members stimulated much grass ralots action, but did not offer the’leadership it desperately needed. The Sinai word can be found in Gramsci : At a certain point in their history, social g:roups separate themselves from their traditional parties . . . the men who constitute, represent and lead the parties are no longer recognised as the true expression of their class or sub-class tfraziune di chse). When such crises occur, the immediate situation becomes delicate and dangerous, because the field! is open to violent solutions, to the activities of bidden. forces (potenze osctwe) represented by providential or charismatic leaders . . . the content (of the situation) is the crisis of the hegemony of the ruling class, which occurs either because the ruling class has failled in that v’ast enterprise where:by it has sought or imposed by force the consensus of the masses (such as a war) or because the masses themselves (especially the peasantry and the petty-bourgeois intelligentsia) have suddenly passed from 3. state of political passiveness to a certain degree of activeness (artiuitb) and have put forward demands which, though inorganic, when taken together constitute a revolution. One speaks of a ‘crisis of authori.ty’ and this is the crisis of hegemony, or the crisis of the State in its entirety. “On these questions sramsci, with his ‘experience of the workers’ councils in Turin after the First Worlri War, had mulch t\r say. The Council was the embryo of the workers’ state, and the sindrcuro s$ould rem,ain independent of it, though the Counci3 would, he hoped, bring about a change, if not a dissolution of the union. He conceived of a deep contradiction between that !egality represented by the unions, and the new legality represented by the Councils. (See Martin Clark: ‘II con&to ;_~ams;ia~o di rivoluzione (1919-1920)‘, in Pietro Rossi (ed.) GIWZSC~’ e r’aCuttura Conttmqwrunea, Rome, Editori Riuniti, 1969.) These vi’ews were expressed in articles in the Ordine Nuovo during the period of the Turin events. D. Lehtnann, Chiie, 1970-1973 123 Of course, as he says, the process varies from country to country, but rhe (content is always the same and the outcome is some form of Bonapartism,, unless the ruling classes cau create a single party of their own - in which case ;the outcome is fascism,” 5 “Note B ml Macchimelii, Rume, Editori Riuniti, 1971, p. 74.