Subido por nicholaskovagiochi

The Corruption Footprints of Nations

Anuncio
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
The Corruption Footprints of Nations
Yanyan Xiao, Manfred Lenzen, Catherine Benoˆıt-Norris, Gregory A. Norris, Joy Murray,
and Arunima Malik
Keywords:
Supporting information is linked
to this article on the JIE website
Summary
In this study, we innovatively apply multiregional input-output analysis to calculate corruption
footprints of nations and show the details of commodities that use the most employment
affected by corruption (EAC), as they flow between countries. Every country’s corruption
footprint includes its domestic corruption and the corruption imported by global supply
chains to meet final demand. Our results show that, generally, the net corruption exporters
are developing countries, with the exception of Italy where corruption is likely to be more
affected by political and cultural factors than economic factors. China is the largest gross
corruption exporter, and India follows close behind, with clothing as one of the industries
in which the most people are affected by corruption. This is because: (1) China and India
are major clothing exporters, thus many workers are employed in the clothing industry
within the country as well as in countries providing intermediate commodities by supply
chains, and (2) corruption is high in China and India. Our results can be useful to identify
where regulations to combat corruption can have the greatest impact. More important, the
method we use can be applied to link corruption to other economic and social aspects of
trade, such as working conditions, thus making it possible to find avenues for tackling the
problem that are not usually considered in anticorruption strategies.
Introduction
Corruption, as one of the biggest global problems (Transparency International 2010), has attracted a great deal of attention worldwide. It exists in all countries and at all levels
of society and government. Corruption is a multidimensional
phenomenon caused by a combination of economic, political,
and social factors. In turn, corruption affects a country’s economic, political, and social performance, exacerbating problems such as inequality and poverty (Chetwynd 2003). Economic performance has been identified as being influenced
by corruption (Lambsdorff 2006). For example, corruption is
viewed as the major obstacle to economic development (Kaufmann 1997; Lambsdorff 2004): World Bank Group President
Jim Yong Kim declared that corruption is “public enemy number
one” in developing countries (World Bank 2013). International
trade is a primary accelerator of economic growth (PACI 2008;
De Jong and Bogmans 2011), but it is generally hampered by corruption. In addition, a relationship between international trade
and corruption seems to exist, because trade openness can affect
corruption levels within countries (Krueger 1974; Gatti 2004;
Tanzi 1998; Jong-Sung and Khagram 2005). Knorich (2004)
finds that the corruption levels in different countries are correlated, indicating that corruption occurring in one country may
influence corruption in other countries, for example, through
businesses being exposed to one another’s corrupt practices.
Such cross-country spillovers might be facilitated by international trade, and thus interactions between trade and corruption
could mean that domestic corruption levels can be influenced
through trading with more or less corrupt countries.
Recent studies have explored social impacts of internationally traded commodities in articles addressing, for example, bad
labor (Simas et al. 2014a, 2014b), social inequality (Alsamawi
et al. 2014; Wiedmann 2016), and occupational health and
Address correspondence to: Manfred Lenzen, ISA, School of Physics A28, 501, The University of Sydney, NSW, AUS 2006. Email: [email protected]
© 2017 by Yale University
DOI: 10.1111/jiec.12537
Editor managing review: Klaus Hubacek
Volume 22, Number 1
68
Journal of Industrial Ecology
www.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jie
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
corruption footprint
industrial ecology
input-output analysis (IOA)
international trade
multiregional input-output tables
social science
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
Norris et al. 2014) with the ultimate consumers of products
produced in corrupt environments (see explanations of Social
Hotspot Database [SHDB] in Methods and Data Sources). For example, in China, Foxconn Technology is a huge contract electronics manufacturer that makes Apple iPhones for the American company, Apple Inc. In 2014, several managers at Foxconn
Technology were arrested for soliciting millions of U.S. dollars
in bribes from suppliers of iPhone parts (ZDnet 2014), which
meant that the final product was tainted by this corruption; or,
in other words, the corruption became “embodied” in the product. Such a supply-chain perspective is commonly understood
as a footprint (Wood et al. 2014; Ivanova et al. 2015; Wiedmann
2016). These iPhones would have been shipped to Apple Inc.,
then distributed all over the world, thus carrying a corruption
footprint to the rest of world.
Our work makes no causal links between trade and corruption. In saying that links can be made between corrupt producers, such as Foxconn in China and final consumers elsewhere
in the world, we are not suggesting that iPhone consumers
cause corruption in the way that, say, consumption of goods
will cause emissions from energy use along the supply chain.
Emissions from energy derived from use of fossil fuels are inevitable; corruption in the production of goods and services is
not. As customers, we can reduce our consumption of goods and
services to decrease energy use and reduce emissions; however,
we cannot simply apply the same method to combat corruption.
One does not cause the other; however, knowingly purchasing
goods and services from a corrupt country may tacitly endorse,
or at least demonstrate tolerance for, its way of doing business. Knowingly purchasing that country’s exports with high
levels of embodied employment, such as clothing or food (illustrated in our results), forgoes a potential to benefit the lives of
thousands of workers. For example, rather than turning a blind
eye, high-profile clothing brands or grocery chains can accept
some responsibility for investigating corruption in the supply
chain. They can, for example, challenge illegal clothing factories that thrive on bribery of building inspectors as in the case
of the Rana Plaza fire (see below) (Transparency International
2014b) or nonenforcement of chemical handling regulations
as in the case of banana growers (Robinson 2010). They can
accept some responsibility for EAC embodied in their supply
chains and work with government bodies, industry regulators,
and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) to improve, for
example, inspection of working conditions and enforcement of
regulations.
As consumers, we can join with others to pressure global
brands and governments to combat corruption wherever it is
found in the supply chain. This already happens in some instances, supported by media publicity or individual case studies.
For example, according to news reports, people in Ukraine are
keen to encourage the world’s leading furnishing chain IKEA to
open stores in their country because of its reputation for combatting corruption. The Ukraine government hopes that IKEA
will help the spread of anticorruption attitudes and strategies
throughout local industries (Newsweek 2015). Our study will
assist in such campaigns by providing information about where
Xiao et al., The Cor r uption Footprints of Nations
69
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
safety (Alsamawi 2015). In a similar vein, our study offers a comprehensive picture of corruption embodied in globalized trade.
In this work, we link employment affected by corruption with
centers of consumption by using multiregional input-output
(MRIO) analysis (Leontief and Strout 1963). This method has
been used previously at multiple scales (Hubacek et al. 2014) for
analyzing the supply-chain effects of international trade on various environmental and social indicators, such as carbon dioxide
emissions (Feng et al. 2013; Kanemoto et al. 2014), scarce water
(Lenzen et al. 2013a), water use (Feng et al. 2011), air pollutants (Kanemoto et al. 2014), land use (Hubacek and Giljum
2003; Yu et al. 2013), material use (Giljum and Hubacek 2004;
Wiedmann et al. 2015), species threats (Lenzen et al. 2012b;
Moran et al. 2016), bad labor practices (Simas et al. 2014a,
2014b), social inequality (Alsamawi et al. 2014; Wiedmann
2016), occupational health and safety (Alsamawi, 2015), civil
war (Moran et al. 2015), and global value chains (Los et al.
2015). It is used in our study to analyze international supplychain effects in terms of corruption. Using the detailed Eora
MRIO database (Lenzen et al. 2012a, 2013b), we calculate corruption footprints for 189 countries. Every country’s corruption
footprint includes its domestic workers affected by corruption
and the workers affected by corruption embodied in goods imported
by global supply chains to meet final demand.
In the following discussion, we simplify the term workers
affected by corruption embodied in goods, instead using the short
form: corruption embodied in goods. We investigate commodities
flowing along trade routes between corrupt countries and to the
rest of the world. We detail those commodities that embody
the highest levels of employment from the most corrupt countries. We refer to these commodities as commodities embodying
high levels of employment (or numbers of workers) affected by corruption (EAC) (see the explanation of EAC in Construction of
Corruption-Weighted Employment Conversion Matrix).
In using the term affected by corruption, we imply that corruption has consequences for workers. The consensus seems to
be that, in its broadest terms, corruption has economic consequences. According to Dal Bo´ and Rossi (2007), there are
economic consequences associated with inefficiencies at the
firm level, which, in turn, affect a country’s overall prosperity. This is compounded by the damage that corruption does
to the country’s reputation, which, in turn, inhibits foreign investment, trade, and, ultimately, economic growth (Corruption
Watch 2016). Other consequences may be more localized and
may have highly adverse effects on individual workers and communities. For example, an Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) issues paper on corruption and
economic growth (OECD 2013) also discusses impacts of corruption on development of human capital, public services, welfare, distribution of income, and disregard for the environment.
Below, we also cite instances of bribery that has catastrophic
effects on the health and safety of workers.
The particular novelty of our work is that we link the occurrence of EAC with the global trade routes of commodities that
are being produced in corrupt countries. Thus, we are able to
connect corruption in social hotspot1 countries (Norris 2014;
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
Methods and Data Sources
Basic Input-Output Theory and Extended
Input-Output Analysis
Input-output (I-O) analysis (IOA) is an economic technique
developed by Russian-born economist Wassily Leontief in the
1930s (Leontief 1936). It shows the complex interdependencies
between production and consumption across all sectors of an
M
economy. The equation x = (I − A) −1 y1 gives all direct and
indirect links between an economy’s gross output x and its final
demand y (see the Supporting Information available on the
Journal’s website for detailed I-O algebra).
I-O accounts can be extended with “satellite” accounts to
include a range of nonmonetary indicators (Leontief and Ford
1970). Extended IOA has been intensively applied to investigate the relationships between nonmonetary and monetary
flows throughout the entire global economy (Lenzen et al.
2012b, 2013a; Moran and Geschke 2013; Wiedmann et al.
2015; Hoekstra 2010). Such relationships can be used to illuminate social and environmental issues in the supply chain.
The satellite account K is sized S×N, with elements Khj
(h = 1, 2, . . . , S) that represent nonmonetary indicators’ input
for the production in economic sector j. Defining q = Kx̂ −1 ,
where q (also sized S×N) is the direct physical indicator intensity. The direct and indirect flows through the entire economy
can be enumerated in terms of the nonmonetary indicators by
equation (1):
K = qx = q(I − A)−1y1 M = qLy1 M ,
(1)
where qx represents the production-side breakdown of total indicators use K, and qLy represent its consumption-side breakdown.
Corruption Satellite and Footprint Account
In this study, the satellite account K holds information on
the level of corruption for 189 countries included in the Eora
country list (see table S2 in the supporting information on the
Web) and a combined 15,979 industry sectors. With x holding
70
Journal of Industrial Ecology
gross output for the same country and sector set, the corruption
footprint K can be calculated as shown by equation (2):
K = Kx̂−1 (I − A)−1y1 M
(2)
Every country’s corruption footprint is defined from a
consumption-based perspective, which includes its domestic
corruption and the corruption imported from all other countries, embodied in goods and services required for meeting its
final demand.2
Net corruption trade in one country is defined as its corruption embodied in imports minus corruption embodied in
exports.
Data Sources
Three types of databases are used in this work.
1. Corruption databases: Corruption perception indices for
countries are obtained from Transparency International
(1995); control of corruption indices for countries are
obtained from the World Bank (2015); irregular payment
and bribe indices are obtained from the World Economic
Forum (2011).
2. Employment databases: The employment data measured
in full-time equivalent (FTE) person-years by sectors and
countries are gained from the International Labor Organization’s (ILO) LABORSTA database (ILO 2012) and
the United Nations System of National Accounts Official
Country database (UNSD 2011).
3. MRIO database: Interindustry transaction data are downloaded from the Eora global Multi-Region Input-Output
(MRIO) database (www.worldmrio.com).
The corruption-weighted employment in one country is estimated by multiplying employment data with the corruption
index. Then, it is subjected to the demand-pull calculus of an
extended I-O model to calculate corruption footprints. These
calculations are carried out for the time period 1995–2011.
However, in this article, we only present the corruption footprints using the latest data for the year 2011.
Construction of Corruption Index Conversion Matrix
The commonly accepted definition of corruption is “the
abuse of public power for private benefit” (Lamsdorff 2007;
Kaufmann et al. 2011). Since corruption cannot be measured
directly (Rohwer 2009), some international organizations have
created indicators to assess the corruption status in different
countries. The three most widely used corruption indices are
the Corruption Perception Index (CPI), the Control of Corruption Index (CCI), and the Irregular Payments and Bribe
Index (IPB). The comparison of these three indices is shown in
table 1.
The CPI is an aggregate index, collected from a wide and
various range of business and expert views. It covers both the
administrative and political aspects of corruption, but only
focuses on the public sectors (Transparency International
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
to look for high levels of employment affected by corruption and
hence where to concentrate efforts to have the greatest effect
on the most workers.
The attribution of corruption to consumers has not previously been considered anywhere in the existing literature. Our
results provide a comprehensive picture of employment affected
by corruption embodied in internationally traded commodities,
which shows the number of workers who are suffering effects of
corruption, such as bribery, because of international trade. We
reveal where to look for high levels of employment affected by
corruption and hence where to concentrate efforts to uncover
the details of corruption. Our work can therefore benefit anticorruption campaigns that involve governments, NGOs, and
national and international law enforcement agencies (Huther
and Shah 2000).
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
Table 1 Comparison of three most widely used corruption indices
Database
Source
Country
coverage
Time
coverage
Definition
Transparency
International
(1995)
41-183
1995–2014
Before 2012: to a scale of 0 to 10, where 10 equals
an entirely clean country and 0 equals a
country where business transactions are
entirely dominated by kickbacks, extortion,
etc. No country scores either 10 or 0. After
2012: to a scale of 0 to 100, where 0 equals
the highest level of perceived corruption and
100 equals the lowest level of perceived
corruption.
Control of
Corruption
Index
World Bank (2015)
184-212
1996–2013
Estimate of governance (ranges from
approximately –2.5 [weak] to 2.5 [strong]
governance performance).
Irregular Payment
and Bribe
World Economic
Forum (2011)
139-148
2010–2014
In every country, how common is it for firms to
make undocumented extra payments or bribes
connected with (a) imports and exports; (b)
public utilities; (c) annual tax payments; (d)
awarding of public contracts and licenses; (e)
obtaining favourable judicial decisions. In each
case, the answer ranges from 1 (very common)
to 7 (never occurs).
1995). The CCI is also an aggregate index, captured from multiple sources, including enterprise, citizen, and expert survey
respondents (World Bank 2015). The CCI also measures the
corruption of private sectors, which covers more than the commonly accepted definition of corruption (Rohwer 2009). Both
the CPI and CCI are often combined (June et al. 2008), and
there exists an extremely high correlation between the CPI and
CCI (Donchev and Ujhely 2007).
The IPB is a single-source index, gained from a large number of business leaders’ perceptions on undocumented extra
payments or bribes in their firms. This index is used in the calculation of the Global Competitiveness Index (GCI), whereas
the GCI is on the source list for both CPI and CCI calculations
(World Economic Forum 2011).
As shown in table S1 in the supporting information on the
Web, the three indices use different scales to measure corruption. The CCI and IPB use one scale each, whereas the CPI has
changed its scale from 0 to 10 to 0 to 100 since 2012. Given
that the CPI is the most widely used corruption database (Tansparency International 2014a), we use CPI data as our main data
source and fill in missing data using the CCI and IPB indices
(table 2). To this end, we estimate a mapping function that
we use to translate CCI and IPB indices into the CPI scale
(figure 1). In order to use corruption data on the same scale,
the CPI’s 0 to 100 scale is adopted in our study. First, CPI data
before 2012 are converted to a 0 to 100 scale by multiplication
of 10; second, the correlation functions between CCI and CPI,
as well as IPB and CPI, are found by polynomial curve fitting,
respectively (R2 is used to test the goodness of fit for the curve
fitting functions; see table S3 in the supporting information on
the Web); third, according to the correlation functions, CCI
Table 2 Data source contribution for corruption index conversion
matrix
Corruption index
CPI
CCI
IPB
Extrapolation
No. of data points
Percentage
2,637
874
1
728
62.2
20.6
0.02
17.2
Note: CPI = Corruption Perception Index, and CCI = the Control of
Corruption Index; IPB = Irregular Payments and Bribe Index.
and IPB data are converted to the CPI’s 0 to 100 scale. Data
missing in all databases have been estimated by extrapolation.
All CPI, CCI, and IPB data are shown at the national level
and as time series. Take figure 1 (top panel) as an example: The
CPI has a country coverage of 41 to 183 countries and a time
coverage from 1995 to 2014, whereas the CCI has a country
coverage of 184 to 212 countries and a time coverage from
1996 to 2013. The overlapping data in CPI and CCI represent
a CPI-to-CCI pair in a certain year. The correlation function
is thus estimated based on many such overlapping data points,
thus making the conversion quite accurate.
Construction of Corruption-Weighted Employment
Conversion Matrix
Because of its illicit nature, corruption can only be measured indirectly. The most widely accepted approach to corruption measurement is that of perceptions of corruption. All
three indices used in this study subscribe to this approach. By
Xiao et al., The Cor r uption Footprints of Nations
71
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
Corruption
Perception Index
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
definition, corruption perception indices are subjective and thus
cannot depict accurate corruption levels in every economic
sector across a country’s entire economy. We use corruptionweighted employment K = E * κ to measure corruption levels.
In this equation, employment data E have sector details, with
the unit in FTE person-years, corruption perception index can
be used as national corruption weights κ for scaling E in order
to obtain the estimation of corruption-weighted employment in
every economic sector in all countries. These sectoral results in
corruption-weighted employment can be interpreted as EAC.
Thus, EAC is the unit in our research. The bigger the values,
the higher the extent of corruption harming people. It should
be noted that, in our research, the corruption level in a given
sector is defined according to the number of workers in that
sector and the country’s overall corruption risk; more workers
in the sector means a greater number of people suffering from
the effects of corruption, for example, of bribery to avoid build-
72
Journal of Industrial Ecology
ing regulation compliance. This is an imperfect measure; when
detailed sectoral corruption data are available in the future,
they can be combined with the current results to show the real
corruption variations among sectors.
The equation we use above follows the practice of the World
Health Organization (Driscoll et al. 2004) on the estimation of
disease risks and the practice of the SHDB (Norris 2014; Norris
et al. 2014) on the social risk estimations for over 100 different
indicators. In the estimation of disease risks, disability-adjusted
life years, which are generated from each country’s population
with occupational exposure for certain disease, is used for showing disease risk levels, whereas in SHDB, work hours, obtained
by multiplying employment-hours and social risk levels, is used
for expressing absolute social risk. In our research, we borrowed
the idea both from the disease estimation and social impacts
estimation. We treat the social risk, corruption, as a “disease”
in the society and use EAC (the unit is the same as full-time
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
Figure 1 CPI-to-CCI (top) and CPI-to-IPB (bottom) correlations. CPI = Corruption Perception Index, and CCI = the Control of
Corruption Index; IPB = Irregular Payments and Bribe Index.
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
–1.0
0.1
0.3
0.5
0.7
0.9
1.1
Net corruption imports / 1000 cap
Figure 2 Top ten importers (upper bars) and bottom ten exporters (lower bars) of corruption. Although Hong Kong is a Special
Administrative Region of China, it is treated as a country in this study. cap = capita.
equivalent and expressed in work hours) as the measurement
unit. The corruption index acts as a “disease risk”; thus, the
number of workers who are suffering from corruption in a sector
can be expressed by multiplying the corruption index by the
employment data.
Given that corruption data are only available at a national
scale, we assume that there is no difference in corruption risk
exposure among sectors in one country, and then use employment in every sector as the currency to convert corruption
indices into an additive quantity. Note that although Hong
Kong is a Special Administrative Region of China and not a
nation, corruption data are available for Hong Kong and it is
treated as a country in this study.
The databases on corruption hold indices that characterize
the degree of corruption in various countries. Such indices are
not additive, because, as with other relative quantities, adding
two numbers on corruption degrees does not make sense. However, a Leontief-type IOA demands that the quantities in a
satellite account be additive, in order to enable the accumulation of impact along supply-chain transactions.
In order to become additive, corruption indices must be used
as weights for an additive “currency” quantity. The usage of such
currencies is also known from other I-O studies. For example,
Lenzen and colleagues (Lenzen 2013a) use water use in liters
to enable an IOA of water scarcity where scarcity data were
available only as indices. Similarly, Alsamawi and colleagues
(2014) use employment as currency for their I-O study of Ginitype inequality indices.
Therefore, the rationale for converting corruption indices
into an additive quantity is that corruption indices can approximately be treated like percentage measures, so, in our study, the
EAC in every sector is proportional to employment. In other
words, if one sector has twice as many employees as in another
sector, the employment affected by corruption in this sector is
twice as high as in the other. The assumption that all the sectors
in one country have the same exposure risk to corruption is one
of the limitations of our research. We made this assumption
for three main reasons: First, although the three sets of raw
corruption perception data that we have used (CPI, CCI, and
IPB) are the most reliable and acceptable data we can obtain
with a world scope, they are only obtainable at a national level,
but not at a sector level. Second, there exists a large regional
disparity in corruption perception (Song and Cheng 2012),
with the exposure risk perception in one region generally not
being applicable to another region. Third, in many countries,
corruption is both pervasive and/or arbitrary (Lee and Oh 2007;
Varese 2000), thus lending some credibility to the assumption
of a uniform distribution across all sectors in each individual
country.
Results and Discussion
The top net corruption exporters and importers are shown
in figure 2. This result shows a clear distinction in net corruption per capita for developed and developing economies.
The top ten net corruption importers tend to be the developed countries, whereas the top ten net corruption exporters
are developing countries. This is mainly because the developed
world’s imported goods and services are mostly produced in developing countries, where corruption levels are much higher.
Consumption of imported goods and services that have corruption embodied in their production affects the corruption
footprint in countries that are not affected by corruption or
affected to a lesser extent.
Xiao et al., The Cor r uption Footprints of Nations
73
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
Hong Kong
Kuwait
United Arab Emirates
Switzerland
Australia
Norway
Singapore
Qatar
USA
United Kingdom
Vietnam
Guatemala
Malaysia
China
Uganda
Thailand
Tanzania
Cambodia
Tajikistan
Madagascar
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
The world’s demand for goods and services with the highest embodied corruption (figure 3) shows that China is the
biggest corruption exporter. It occupies seven spots in the top
ten gross corruption flows. Further, China is identified as the
exporter in the top three gross corruption flows: China to Hong
Kong; China to United States; and China to Japan. One understandable reason to explain this trend is the magnitude of
manufacturing exports from China. China has been named factory of the world, a name given to it by the Japanese Ministry of
Economy, Trade and Industry (METI) in 2001 (METI 2002).
A large proportion of the working population of China works
in manufacturing. Though the corruption index for China is
in the middle status among all countries, the multiplication of
this corruption index and the employment value is extremely
large, which inevitably means that a high level of employment
affected by corruption embodied in goods made in China flows
to regions that are not corrupt, or corrupt to a lesser extent,
through international trade.
India is the second-biggest corruption exporter. It ranks
fourth place with exports to the United States and ninth place
with exports to United Arab Emirates. Corruption is a pervasive phenomenon in India, perceived to exist at all levels of
the political and administrative system (Chêne et al. 2009).
One historical root of India’s corruption is that a business needs
to give bribes to obtain or renew various licenses and permits
from different goverments and organizations (Deloitte 2014;
Xu 2014). It seems hard to tell where corruption originates in
this complex situation. The method outlined above distributes
the country’s corruption throughout the economy according
to each sector’s employment numbers. The results that follow
provide details of dominant exports with the highest levels of
employment from the most corrupt countries, thereby providing
a picture of where to find the largest concentrations of employment affected by corruption. These countries and commodities
74
Journal of Industrial Ecology
will be an indication of where strategies to combat corruption
will have the greatest effect for good.
We have investigated supply chains with high concentrations of employment affected by corruption to provide further information about corruption embodied in international
trade (tables S4 and S5 in the supporting information on the
Web). Our investigation shows that clothing, leather products,
petroleum, transportation construction and equipment, food,
and alcohol are the most corruption-intensive commodities.
In particular, clothing is the dominant export product from
Bangladesh, China, and Italy, whereas textiles, the raw material for clothing, is the dominant export product from Pakistan.
Transparency International (2012) has reported that corruption and weak law enforcement are significant problems in most
of the countries that manufacture clothing. Bangladesh, India,
and Vietnam are the main suppliers of low-priced, ready-made
clothing. They also supply the primary products needed for apparel and accessories used in popular Western brands. European
exporters, such as Italy and Spain, are the main consumers of
low-priced primary products; however, by contrast, they are the
main suppliers of high-quality and high-priced apparel.
The link between clothing manufacture and corruption can
be illustrated using Bangladesh as an example. Fires are a serious
risk in clothing factories, particularly, it seems, in Bangladesh
(The Guardian 2013). They have injured or killed hundreds
of workers over the years. Though fire seems to be the direct
cause of deaths, deep-rooted corruption is the driver of these
human tragedies. For example, 1,135 people were killed and
over 2,500 people were injured in Bangladesh’s worst garmentfactory accident—the Rana Plaza fire on 24 April 2013 (Transparency International 2014b). The factories involved were illegally constructed. Safety inspectors prioritized good relations
with managers and gave them advance notice before inspections. Such long-standing corruption resulting in unsafe and
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
Figure 3 Employment affected by corruption (EAC) flow embodied in commodities traded along international supply routes in 2011.
Bre = bread; Car = cars; Clo = clothing; Coc = cocoa; Fab = fabrics; Fis = fish; Fju = fruit juices; Fur = furnitures; Jew = jewellery; Lea =
leather; Mac = machines; Med = medicine; Mpa = motor parts; Pak = packing; Pet = petroleum; Ric = rice; Sta = starch; Tea = tea;
Tex = textiles; Tob = tobacco; Tou = tourism; Toy = toys; Tur = turbines; TV = televisions.
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
Conclusions
In this study, we provide a new perspective on how to account for corruption through global trade routes. By applying
MRIO analysis, we offer a comprehensive picture of global corruption footprints. Our results indicate that top net corruption
per capita is generally from developing countries to wealthy
developed countries. China is the biggest gross corruption exporter and India is close behind. The fact that Italy is the only
wealthy developed country that exports corruption embodied in
commodities can perhaps be attributed to political and cultural
factors rather than economic factors.
All of society is, in some way, responsible for the existence
of corruption, because, knowingly or unknowingly, people are
direct or indirect “sellers” or “buyers” of the world’s products embodying employment affected by corruption (Langseth 1999).
It is unlikely that final consumers willingly support corruption.
However, by our consumption, the industry in which workers
are suffering from the effects of corruption, such as bribery, remains prosperous, thus feeding the corruption. Based on the
corruption footprints of nations calculated by our work, we
have identified the relationships between employment affected
by corruption and final demand through supply chains. For every specific transaction between countries, the corruption-free
country can help its trading partner to ameliorate corruption
using commercial strategies in international trade. Revealing
the commodity details with the highest EAC means that commercial anticorruption strategies can be targeted to export industries where intervention will affect the lives of the highest
number of workers.
Nevertheless, commercial anticorruption strategies do not
simply mean that we stop buying the products with high EAC.
To do so may be to cut off the income of someone who desperately needs it to feed a family. The argument is the same as
that for controlling the illegal phenomenon of child labor in
export industries in developing countries, reducing investment
in the sector may force unemployed children to seek even moreprecarious employment in informal sectors (Panagariya 2001).
Likewise, boycotting the clothing industry may be of little help
in controlling corruption that harms the workers employed in
this sector, but would punish poor workers who consequently
lose their jobs.
Instead of asking big international retailers, such as WalMart, Gap, and H&M, to cancel their orders from the clothing
industry of Bangladesh with its high rate of employment affected
by corruption, consumers can support these multinational companies to work with governments on legislation enforcement
in controlling corruption. Consumers can use their purchasing power to collectively pressure these global companies to
combat corruption. These global companies then can pressure
local government and the industries in which most people are
affected by corruption to develop and enforce anticorruption
laws and regulations. In fact, fighting corruption through global
brands is already being implemented in Bangladesh. Since the
Rana Plaza fire, many multinational companies have signed up
to the Bangladesh Fire and Building Safety Accord, which has
resulted in the inspection to date of 675 factories (Transparency
International 2014b). These improvements are a powerful guarantee against bribes for skipping regular safety inspections. In
addition, some international anticorruption organizations, such
as Transparency International, World Bank, and Corruption
Watch, are performing their duties in monitoring and assisting
anticorruption progress in corrupt countries. The corruption
footprint can also be used by governments for anticorruption
policy development, for example, to design demand-side policies and initiatives that can support domestic governance in
ameliorating corruption.
In addition to assisting in the fight against corruption, this
corruption footprint measure has significance for corruption
research. One is that we provide a new method to measure
Xiao et al., The Cor r uption Footprints of Nations
75
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
overcrowded buildings makes fires almost inevitable. The high
corruption embodied in these factories’ products is exported to
the world through multiple and complex supply chains.
China produces miscellaneous clothing, which includes
top-, middle-, and low-priced products. Its clothing industry
also has a high level of corruption embodied in its exports because of high employment in the clothing supply chain and the
country’s overall corruption rating. The high imported corruption footprint embodied in raw materials for clothing from some
corrupt countries, such as Bangladesh and Pakistan, is another
explanation for China’s high corruption footprint.
Unlike other wealthy developed European countries, Italy
is not a net corruption importer, but an exporter. Generally,
the view is that there exists an inverse relationship between
corruption and development status (Gray and Kaufmann 1998;
Paldam 2002), which suggests that the more corrupt the country is, the more poverty the country has. Obviously, Italy is an
exception to this view. Del Monte and Papagni (2007) have
investigated the determinants of corruption in Italy over nearly
40 years and conclude that the corruption in Italy is much more
affected by political and cultural factors than economic factors.
This is in agreement with Treisman’s (2000) cross-national corruption analysis. More-recent reports also demonstrate that the
weakness of Italian governments and the long history of corruption have helped to embed it in Italian society (Independent
2015; Open Democracy 2015).
As mentioned above, our work has merit for the research
field and civil society. However, it also has limitations. First, we
cannot provide the extent of corruption at the detail of individual establishments, which means that information on corrupt
companies in certain sectors needs to be investigated further
in order to inform consumers about individual cases. Second,
IOA shows uncertainties in several aspects, for example: raw
data errors; assumption deviations; and mischaracterization of
causative sectors (e.g., the clothing industry only refers to clothing in some countries, whereas in other countries the clothing
industry includes textiles, footwear, and accessories production)
(Moran et al. 2016). Third, the assumption we made that every
sector in a country faces the same corruption risk (see explanations in methodology above) can be improved when new data
become available on corruption risk disparity among sectors.
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
Acknowledgments
We thank A. Geschke (University of Sydney) for help in
topic selection and A. Alsamawi (University of Sydney) for
technical assistance in calculations.
Notes
1. Social hotspot countries are the countries of the inputoutput LCI database Social Hotspot Database (SHDB;
http://socialhotspot.org). SHDB is built by Harvard University, providing data of risk levels in social impact categories by country and
sector, which can be used to improve visibility of social hotspots in
supply chains.
2. Mathematically, domestic, and imported footprint components can
be distinguished by disaggregating the corruption footprint K as
K rsij = k ri L rsij ysj , with k = Kx̂−1 and L = (I − A) −1 . The domestic

footprint of country s is then ij K ssij , and the imported footprint is

rs
r =s ,i j K ij .
References
Alsamawi, A., J. Murray, M. Lenzen, K. Kanemoto, and D. Moran.
2014. A novel approach to quantitative accounting of income
inequality. PLoS One 9(10): e110881.
Alsamawi, A. 2015. The Occupational Health and Safety Footprints.
The 5th World Sustainability Forum, 7–9 September, 2015, Basel,
Switzerland.
Chêne M., U4 Helpdesk, and Transparency International. 2009.
Overview of corruption and anti- corruption efforts in India. U4
Expert Answer. www.u4.no/publications/overview-of-corruption-and-anti-corruption-efforts-in-india./ Accessed 21 December 2016.
Chetwynd, E., F. Chetwynd, and B. Spector. 2003. Corruption and
poverty: A review of recent literature. Washington, DC: Management Systems International.
Corruption Watch. 2016. What is corruption: We are all affected.
www.corruptionwatch.org.za/learn-about-corruption/what-iscorruption/we-are-all-affected/. Accessed 25 August 2016.
Dal B ´o, E. and M. A. Rossi. 2007. Corruption and inefficiency: Theory
and evidence from electrical utilities. Journal of Public Economics
91(5–6): 939–962.
76
Journal of Industrial Ecology
De Jong, E. and C. Bogmans. 2011. Does corruption discourage international trade? European Journal of Political Economy 27(2):
385–398.
Del Monte, A. and E. Papagni. 2007. The determinants of corruption
in Italy: Regional panel data analysis. European Journal of Political
Economy 23(2): 379–396.
Deloitte. 2014. Managing corruption risks in India. www2.deloitte.
com/content/dam/Deloitte/us/Documents/finance/us-fasmanagingcorruptionriskInIndia-05162014.PDF.
Donchev, D. and G. Ujhelyi. 2007. Do corruption indices measure corruption? Working Paper, Economics Deparment, Harvard University, 25 March 2007.
Driscoll, T., K. Steenland, D. I. Nelson, and J. Leigh. 2004 Occupational
airborne particulates: Assessing the environmental burden of disease
at national and local levels. Environmental burden of disease series,
no. 7 Geneva, Switzerland:. World Health Organization.
Feng, K., A. K. Chapagain, S. Suh, S. Pfister, and K. Hubacek. 2011.
Comparison of bottom-up and top-down approaches to calculating the water footprints of nations. Economic Systems Research 23:
371–385.
Feng, K., S. J. Davis, L. Sun, X. Li, D. Guan,W. Liu, Z. Liu, and K.
Hubacek. 2013. Outsourcing CO2 within China. Proceedings of
the National Academy of Sciences 110(28): 11654–11659.
Gatti, R. 2004. Explaining corruption: Are open countries less corrupt?
Journal of International Development 16(6): 851–861.
Giljum, S. and K. Hubacek. 2004. Alternative approaches of physical
input-output analysis to estimate primary material inputs of production and consumption activities. Economic Systems Research
16(3): 301–310.
Gray, C. and D. Kaufmann. 1998. Corruption and development. Finance and Development 35(1): 6–10
Hoekstra, R. 2010. A complete database of peer-reviewed articles
on environmentally extended input–output analysis.18th International Input–Output Conference of the International Input–
Output Association. Sydney: Statistics Netherlands.
Hubacek, K. and S. Giljum. 2003. Applying physical input–output
analysis to estimate land appropriation (ecological footprints) of
international trade activities. Ecological Economics 44(1): 137–
151.
Hubacek, K., K. Feng, J. C. Minx, S. Pfister, and N. Zhou. 2014. Teleconnecting consumption to environmental impacts at multiple
spatial scales. Journal of Industrial Ecology 18(1): 7–9.
Huther, J. and A. Shah. 2000. Anti-corruption policies and programs:
A framework for evaluation. Vol. 2501. Washington, DC: World
Bank Publications.
ILO (International Labor Organization). 2012 LABORSTA—Main
statistics (annual): Employment general level, by economic activity, by occupation, by status in employment. http://laborsta.ilo.org.proxy.lib.duke.edu
Geneva, Switzerland: International Labor Organization.
Independent. 2015. Corruption in Italy “worse than ever” as
minister quits over links with gang accused of bribery.
www.independent.co.uk/news/world/europe/corruption-initaly-worse-than-ever-as-minister-quits-over-links-with-gangaccused-of-bribery-10124024.html.
Ivanova, D., K. Stadler, K. Steen-Olsen, R. Wood, G. Vita, A. Tukker,
and E. G. Hertwich. 2015. Environmental impact assessment of
household consumption. Journal of Industrial Ecology. https://doi.
org/10.1111/jiec.12371.
Jong-Sung, Y. and S. Khagram. 2005. A comparative study of inequality and corruption. American Sociological Review 70(1):
136–157.
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
corruption levels across countries, which is a useful supplement
to current corruption measurement. The second is, based
on the corruption perception data at a national level, we
estimate the levels of employment affected by corruption with
sectoral resolution along supply chains, thereby providing
more-detailed data in this area. Third, by adopting IOA,
we can, for the first time, show consumers’ responsibility in
anticorruption campaigning. In summary, we provide the
possibility of ameliorating corruption through commercial
avenues by tackling the main exported commodities from the
main net corruption exporting countries. They are the ones
that embody the highest levels of employment affected by
corruption along the supply chain and therefore the areas that,
if improved, will yield the greatest relief for the most people.
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
data analysis for sustainable development, edited by T. Yu et al.
CRC data mining and knowledge discovery series. Abingdon,
UK: Chapman & Hall.
Moran, D., D. McBain, K. Kanemoto, M. Lenzen, and A. Geschke.
2015. Global supply chains of coltan. Journal of Industrial Ecology
19(3): 357–365.
Moran, D., M. Petersone, and F. Verones. 2016. On the suitability of
input-output analysis for calculating product-specific biodiversity
footprints. Ecological Indicators 60: 192–201.
Newsweek. 2015. Ukraine asks Ikea to open store to prove
country’s progress in fight against corruption. http://europe.
newsweek.com/ukraine-asks-ikea-open-store-prove-countrysprogress-fight-against-corruption-334874. Accessed 15 October
2015.
Norris, C. B. 2014. Data for social LCA. The International Journal of
Life Cycle Assessment 19(2): 261–265.
Norris, C. B., G. A. Norris, and D. Aulisio. 2014. Efficient assessment
of social hotspots in the supply chains of 100 product categories
using the social hotspots database. Sustainability 6(10): 6973–
6984.
OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).
2013. Issues paper on corruption and economic growth. www.
oecd.org/g20/topics/anti-corruption/issues-paper-on-corruptionand-economic-growth.htm. Accessed 25 August 2016.
Open Democracy. 2015. Corruption in Italy: A resilient equilibrium.
www.opendemocracy.net/can-europe-make-it/andrea-capusselavito-intini/corruption-in-italy-resilient-equilibrium. Accessed 9
May 2015.
PACI (International Chamber of Commerce, Transparency International, United Nations Global Compact and the World Economic Forum Partnering Against Corruption Initiative). 2008.
Clean business is good business. www.anticorruptionday.org/
documents/actagainstcorruption/print/materials2013/corr13_fs_
DEVELOPMENT_EN_HIRES.pdf. Accessed 21 December
2016.
Paldam, M. 2002. The cross-country pattern of corruption: Economics,
culture and the seesaw dynamics. European Journal of Political
Economy 18(2): 215–240.
Panagariya, A. 2001. Trade-labour link: A post-Seattle analysis. In
Globalization under threat, 101–123. Cheltenham, UK: Edward
Elgar.
Robinson, P. 2010. Responsible retailing: The practice of CSR in banana plantations in Costa Rica. Journal of Business Ethics 91(s2):
279–289.
Rohwer, A. 2009. Measuring corruption: A comparison between the
Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions Index and
the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators. CESifo
DICE Report 7(3): 42–52.
Simas, M. S., L. Golsteijn, M. A. J. Huijbregts, R. Wood, and E.
G. Hertwich. 2014a. The “bad labor” footprint: Quantifying the
social impacts of globalization. Sustainability 6(11): 7514–7540.
Simas, M. S., R. Wood, and E. Hertwich. 2014b. Labor embodied in
trade: The role of labor and energy productivity and implications
for greenhouse gas emissions. Journal of Industrial Ecology 3(19):
343–356.
Song, X. and W. Cheng. 2012. Perception of corruption in 36 major
Chinese cities: Based on survey of 1,642 experts. Social Indicators
Research 109(2): 211–221.
The Guardian. 2013. Bangladesh factory fires: Fashion industry’s latest crisis. www.theguardian.com/world/2013/dec/08/bangladeshfactory-fires-fashion-latest-crisis. Accessed 9 December 2013.
Xiao et al., The Cor r uption Footprints of Nations
77
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
June, R., M. Laberge, J. Nahem, and G. Integrity. 2008. A users’ guide to
measuring corruption. New York: UNDP Oslo Governance Centre.
Kanemoto, K., D. Moran, M. Lenzen, and A. Geschke. 2014 International trade undermines national emission reduction targets:
New evidence from air pollution. Global Environmental Change
24: 52–59.
Kaufmann, D. 1997. Corruption: The facts. Foreign Policy 107: 114–
131.
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2011. The worldwide governance indicators: Methodology and analytical issues. Hague Journal on the Rule of Law 3(02): 220–246.
Knorich, J. 2004. International Trade and Corruption: The Influence of
Trading Partners. Seton Hall University Dissertations and Theses
(ETDs). Paper 682. New Jersey, United States.
Krueger, A. O. 1974. The political economy of the rent-seeking society.
The American Economic Review 64(3): 291–303.
Lambsdorff, J. G. 2004. How corruption affects economic development.
Global Corruption Report: 310–212.
Lambsdorff, J. G. 2006. Causes and consequences of corruption: What
do we know from a cross-section of countries. International handbook on the economics of corruption, edited by S. Rose-Ackerman,
Vol. 1, 3–51. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Lambsdorff, J. G. 2007. The institutional economics of corruption and
reform: Theory, evidence and policy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
Langseth, P. 1999. Prevention: An effective tool to reduce corruption.
Paper presented at the ISPAC conference on Responding to the
Challenge of Corruption, 19 November, Milan, Italy.
Lee, S. H. and K. K. Oh. 2007. Corruption in Asia: Pervasiveness and
arbitrariness. Asia Pacific Journal of Management 24(1): 97–114.
Lenzen, M., K. Kanemoto, D. Moran, and A. Geschke. 2012a. Mapping the structure of the world economy. Environmental Science &
Technology 46(15): 8374–8381.
Lenzen, M., D. Moran, A. Bhaduri, K. Kanemoto, M. Bekchanov, A.
Geschke, and B. Foran. 2013a. International trade of scarce water.
Ecological Economics 94: 78–85.
Lenzen, M., D. Moran, K. Kanemoto, B. Foran, L. Lobefaro, and A.
Geschke. 2012b. International trade drives biodiversity threats in
developing nations. Nature 486(7401): 109–112.
Lenzen, M., D. Moran, K. Kanemoto, and A. Geschke. 2013b. Building
Eora: A global multi-region input-output database at high country
and sector resolution. Economic Systems Research 25(1): 20–49.
Leontief, W. 1936. Quantitative input and output relations in the
economic system of the United States. Review of Economics and
Statistics 18(3): 105–125.
Leontief, W. 1966. Input-output economics. New York: Oxford University Press.
Leontief, W. and D. Ford. 1970. Environmental repercussions and
the economic structure: An input-output approach. Review of
Economics and Statistics 52(3): 262–271.
Leontief, W. W. and A. A. Strout. 1963. Multiregional input-output
analysis. In Structural interdependence and economic development,
edited by T. Barna, 119–149. London: Macmillan.
Los, B., M. P. Timmer, and G. J. Vries. 2015. How global are global
value chains? A new approach to measure international fragmentation. Journal of Regional Science 55(1): 66–92.
METI (Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry). 2002. METI white
paper year 2001. www.meti.go.jp/english/report/index.html. 31
December 31 2006.
Moran, D. and A. Geschke. 2013. Tracing embodied CO2 in trade using
high-resolution input-output tables. In Computational intelligent
R E S E A R C H A N D A N A LY S I S
World Bank. 2013. Corruption is “public enemy number one”
in developing countries, says World Bank Group President Kim. www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/
12/19/corruption-developing-countries-world-bank-grouppresident-kim. Accessed 19 December 2013.
World Bank. 2015. Worldwide Governance Indicators.
http://info.worldbank.org.proxy.lib.duke.edu/governance/wgi/index.aspx#doc,
World Economic Forum. 2011. The Global Competitiveness Report 2010–2011. www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_
GlobalCompetitivenessReport_2010-11.pdf.
Xu, B. 2014. Governance in India: Corruption. Council on Foreign
Relations. www.cfr.org/corruption-and-bribery/governance-indiacorruption/p31823. Accessed 4 September 2014.
Yu, Y., K. Feng, and K. Hubacek. 2013. Tele-connecting local consumption to global land use. Global Environmental Change 23(5):
1178–1186.
ZDnet. 2014. Foxconn senior management arrested for alleged
millions in kickbacks. www.zdnet.com/article/foxconn-seniormanagement-arrested-for-alleged-millions-in-kickbacks/.
Accessed 22 January 2014.
About the Authors
Yanyan Xiao is a doctoral candidate, Manfred Lenzen is
a professor of sustainability research, Joy Murray is a senior
research fellow, and Arunima Malik is a lecturer, all at the
center for Integrated Sustainability Analysis at the University
of Sydney, Sydney, New South Wales, Australia. Catherine
Benoˆıt-Norris is the VP of social sustainability at New Earth
where she directs the Social Hotspots Database project, and
Greg Norris is the executive director of New Earth, both at
Harvard School of Public Health, Boston, MA, USA.
Supporting Information
Supporting information is linked to this article on the JIE website:
Supporting Information S1: This supporting information provides detailed input-output algebra, a list of corruption data
sources, a list of countries in Eora, details regarding the R 2 in polynomial curve fitting process κ , and ranked lists of the main
net corruption importers and exporters.
78
Journal of Industrial Ecology
Printed by [Duke University Libraries Box 90187 - 152.003.102.254 - /doi/epdf/10.1111/jiec.12537] at [11/11/2020].
Transparency International. 1995. 1995 TI Corruption Index.
www.transparency.org/files/content/tool/1995_CPI_EN.pdf. Accessed 15 July 1995.
Transparency International. 2010. Why corruption matters.
www.transparency.org.uk/corruption/why-it-matters.
Transparency International. 2012. Corruption and the fate of
the people who make your clothes. http://blog.transparency.
org/2012/12/07/corruption-and-the-fate-of-the-people-whomake-your-clothes/. Accessed 7 December 2012.
Transparency International. 2014a. Corruption perceptions index
2014: In detail. www.transparency.org/cpi2014/in_detail.
Transparency International. 2014b. Rana Plaza one year on: What has
changed? www.transparency.org/news/feature/rana_plaza_one_
year_on_what_has_changed. Accessed 24 April 2014.
Treisman, D. 2000. The causes of corruption: A cross-national study.
Journal of Public Economics 76(3): 399–457.
UNSD (United Nations Statistics Division). 2011. National accounts
official data. New York: United Nations Statistics Division.
http://data.un.org.proxy.lib.duke.edu/Browse.aspx?d=SNA.
Varese, F. 2000. Pervasive corruption. In Economic crime in Russia,
99–111. New York: Springer.
Wiedmann, T. O., H. Schandl, M. Lenzen, D. Moran, S. Suh, J. West,
and K. Kanemoto. 2015. The material footprint of nations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of
America 112(20): 6271–6276.
Wiedmann, T. 2016 Impacts embodied in global trade flows. In Taking stock of industrial ecology, part I, edited by R. Clift and A.
Druckman, 159–180. Cham, Switzerland: Springer International
AG.
Wood, R., K. Stadler, T. Bulavskaya, S. Lutter, S. Giljum, A. de Koning, J. Kuenen, et al. 2014 Global sustainability accounting—
Developing EXIOBASE for multi-regional footprint analysis. Sustainability 7(1): 138–163.
Descargar