Nationalism, ideological identification and solidarity: the attitudinal sphere By Enric Martínez-Herrera (CEPC) and Inés Calzada (CSIC) c/e: [email protected] Versión 11/11/09 NB: DRAFT/BORRADOR Comments most welcome For citation queries, please ask at the e/m above Presentation at CANS meeting. Brussels, 12-13 November 2009 1 Nationalism, ideological identification and solidarity: the attitudinal sphere1 Enric Martínez-Herrera (CEPC) and Inés Calzada (CSIC) Are nationalists progressive? Which nationalists are progressive and which are not? During the last decade and a half some prominent political theorists have advanced an attractive blend of nationalism with social-democratic and liberal ideas. One of their most appealing yet not unproblematic or uncontroversial claims is that national identification contributes to strengthen solidarity and support for re-distributive policies. Notwithstanding conceptual and theoretical difficulties to match progressive and nationalist tenets, however, different kinds of empirical evidence show that, more often than not, nationalism is right-wing. In this paper we assess the relationship between national identification, on the one hand, and left-right self-identification and economic solidarity, on the other hand. The analysis of the relationship between national identification and attitudes towards solidarity and redistribution allows us to go beyond citizens’ perception of themselves as progressive or conservative. Individuals’ self-perceptions as progressive or conservative may well be flawed by their perceptions of the social desirability of these political labels in their socio-political milieu. In this sense, the study of the attitudes towards solidarity and redistribution affords the possibility not to take for granted individuals generic ideological self-placements and to test their solidarity in different instances of support to redistribution. In addition to it, this study compares the orientation towards ideological identification and solidarity at different instances of nationalism. In particular, by regarding Spanish, Catalan and Galician nationalisms, it weights the solidarity credentials of both statewide nationalism and minority nationalism. 1 The attitudinal data stem from a survey conducted in May 2009 in This communication and the social survey it is based upon have been produced within the frame of the project “Citizenship after the Nation State?” (CANS), supported by Spain’s Ministry of Science and Innovation (SEJ2007-30242-E/SOCI) and the European Science Foundation. 2 representative samples of citizen’s living in three Spanish autonomous regions – Catalonia, Galicia and Castilla-La Mancha. The paper begins by engaging different claims according to which nationalism has beneficent effects on solidarity and redistribution and by specifying some widely accepted definitions of the concepts “nationalism”, “national identification” and “left and right”. In particular, it pays attention to some basic postulates of the so-called “liberal nationalism” stream in contemporary political theory. The paper then turns to empirically analyze the relationship between individuals’ national identifications and their identifications with the generic labels “left and right” on a widely used linear scale. Next the paper evaluates more specific solidarity attitudes – solidarity towards people in need, irrespective of their geographical location; and, subsequently, solidarity between different regions of the same country. Solidarity, redistribution and “good nationalism” – theoretical claims The intellectual reputation of nationalism since World War II has been quite bad. Nationalism has not only spurred the mass wars that occurred since the end of nineteenth century – in which tens of millions of men and women would die – but also genocide, mass deportation and other mass crimes committed in both wartime and peacetime from the Modern age. Although the struggles of the 1950-60s de- colonization movements partially enhanced its reputation, this improvement soon vanished again because of nationalist violence in many of the new and old states. The 1990s witnessed, however, a two-fold scenario of intellectual revisiting and debate on the subject. On the one hand, a nationalist revival – including increasing racism towards international migrants and their offspring – in Western Europe and, overall, civil wars in former Yugoslavia revived fears about nationalism. On the other, a wave of political thought has made the case that nationalism has a virtuous side. Some authors claim that nationalism not only justifies and generates zero-sum game conflict between groups but also that it can foster genuine cooperation within them. They claim that liberalism it not only compatible with liberal values but also that it helps attain goals of social justice pursued by left liberalism and social-democracy. One of their key theoretical assumptions is that nationalism and the resulting national identity foster citizens’ solidarity and support for national re-distributive policies. By 3 making this claim, they have managed to theoretically bring together two current concerns in political and social theory – the rediscovery of the community and changes in welfare stare regimes. Unfortunately, though, there has been little systematic empirical evidence to support this claim, so this paper aims at empirically testing it – the aim of this study is to empirically evaluate it. During the last decade and a half, there have been different theoretical attempts to revisit nationalism, looking back for some lost communitarian or republican ethical tenets compatible with liberal values and institutions. These attempts have taken place against the background of a rediscovery of community in political science and sociology during the 1990s – some of the most celebrated books of that decade were about social trust and social capital (Inglehart 1990, 1997; Putnam 1993, 2000). The theoretical production of “liberal-nationalists” such as Yael Tamir and David Miller, has gone quite further – they have sought to rescue the community by means of nationalism and national identification. A common theme shared by the most prominent proponents of liberal nationalism is, to borrow Tamir’s (1993) words, “distributive justice.” “Liberal-nationalists” sympathise with nationalism while maintaining some form of liberal stance, and they contend that national identification is necessary for safeguarding citizens’ solidarity at the national level. Moreover, changes of the welfare state since the late 1970s have raised much concern in Western Europe, and Tamir and Miller put national identification to the fore as an potential remedy. Welfare state and national identification seem to influence each other in a non-recursive, reciprocal manner. On the one hand, the state has used the welfare system to gain loyalty and a sense of national solidarity from citizens (Hobsbawm, 1992; Keating, 2001; McEwen, 2002; Moreno and McEwen, 2005). On the other, however, it is often argued that social consent towards distributive and redistributive policies has one of its stronger bases in national identification. Certainly, it has also been expected that support for redistribution could flow from a universalistic sense of justice – regardless of national borders – but this alternative seems to be less in vogue these days. The main hypothesis argues that national identification lends support for national solidarity. It links both variables through a sense of “common good” and “mutual responsibility”. As a matter of fact, distributive and re-distributive policies entail an essential, at least latent conflict, since some individuals or social sections must 4 pay the costs of improving the situation of other individuals or sections. Yet these policies, in special within the frame of a welfare system, often also entail a coordination problem, insofar as most individuals and sections could be made better-off – especially in the long-run. Noticeably, though, many individuals or sections could still be tempted to escape the costs, thus leading to a problem of lack of cooperation. The argument relating national identification and solidarity goes through the notions of common good – taking various meanings – and mutual responsibility. The analogy with the family that some authors put forward (Miller, 1996; Keating, 2001) can be a useful departure point, since it easily evokes both ideas, and it can be interpreted from either a strictly egoistic viewpoint or a less egoistic, perhaps even altruistic one. Yet different meanings of the term “common good” (Dahl, 1989) and a couple of different understandings of the welfare state (Keating, 2001) must be considered altogether. The first two meanings of the term “common good” as applied in relation to national solidarity are neatly individualistic and selfish. First, common good is seen as that which is good for all the members of, or a large majority in, a society. Here national redistribution is understood as a “mutual insurance plan” where reciprocity is expected, and the fact that this plan exists is likely to benefit most members of the society (Keating, 2001). Thus, national identification helps coordinate individuals with a latent shared egoistic interest. Second, nationwide redistribution can be seen as solely making some sections of the society better-off, whereas many sections and single members are unlikely to directly benefit. If the individual believes that she shares a “common interest” (Keating, 2001), “common venture”, “enterprise” or “project” (Taylor, 1996), even “common fate” with her nation fellow-members – as nationalism often induces individuals to perceive themselves – then she can still think in egoistic rational terms that she also benefit from her fellow nationals’ improvement, since she is indirectly affected by their successes and failures (Tamir, 1993). Thus, “common good” is perceived by the selfish individual in terms of such an interdependence – some degree of improvement of her fellow-nationals may also benefit herself. The third sense of “common good” is no more individualistic, but organicist instead. A society or nation is seen as an entity with its own autonomous life – independent to a degree from the individuals forming it – and the common good is 5 referred to as its well-being. Since individuals can perceive a “sense of national interest” (Brown et al., 1998), now the distributive and re-distributive policies are intended to keep or improve the well-being of the social organism. Selfish individuals’ calculations are possible insofar as they believe that the well-being of the organism is also good for its cells – without denying that non-strictly egoistic sacrifices are possible too. The analogy with the family also has the connotation that national identification carries with it a feeling of “mutual responsibility” (Keating, 2001), a “fellow-feeling and mutual concern” (Parekh, 2002), or a “sense of bonding among the people working together” (Taylor, 1996). The analogy is of a limited scope, since members of the nation do not know each other personally, nor do they share most daily life experiences. However, it is assumed that from the fact of identifying with the same social unit – the “nation” – individuals identify also with each other with comparable strength, and even more, they develop an affection for each other. This is indeed a much debatable assumption (Brubaker and Cooper, 2000; Abizadeh, 2002), but it works to rhetorically legitimate the “distributive justice” understanding of re-distributive policies (Tamir, 1993). However, were it true, affection for fellow-nationals would inspire a sense of moral responsibility, obligation towards them, similar– though less intense – to the feelings within a Western ideal family. Therefore, from any of those arguments we should expect that the stronger the individual identifies with her nation, the more supportive will be to redistributive policies. There is little empirical research on this matter. Previous empirical analyses have grounded on a public opinion survey conducted in England and Scotland – the 1997 British General Election Study (Martínez-Herrera 2004, 2009). This survey had two main virtues. First, the survey included a large variety of indicators intended to measure a so-called ‘British national sentiment’ as well as attitudes to the welfare state. The “British national sentiment” was tapped through a wide array of questions comprising exclusionary forms of nationalism as well as softer questions on national identification. In turn, support for the welfare state was tapped through support for policies of public health, public education and financial assistance to people in need. A 6 second virtue was the fact that Great Britain was the country that David Miller bore in mind when prising the allegedly progressive virtues of “liberal nationalism”. As a matter of fact, however, empirical findings disagreed with theoretical claims. Even if controlling by important variables as left-right identification and household income, citizens showing a greater reluctance towards any influence of other countries in British politics as well as holding an uncritical British pride, and citizens showing the stronger British identification and stronger wish to keep Great Britain united, tend to be the least supportive to welfare state schemes. In other words, contrary to liberal nationalist theoretical expectations, the effects on solidarity of both soft national identification and tougher nationalist views were found to be negative. Therefore, Miller’s and Tamir’s hypothesis did not hold in Great Britain. The current piece research supplies a new test for the hypothesis in a different setting and affords the possibility to operationalize national identification as referring to both the state political community and sub-state level national projects. Basic concepts Before testing the above-mentioned hypothesis, however, we need a clarification of what is meant by “national identification” in this literature. First of all, following from Gellner (1983), it could be agreed that “nationalism” is a “principle of political legitimacy”. A principle that states that “the political and the national unit should be congruent”, understanding the “national unit” as defined by ethno-cultural – e.g. religious and/or linguistic – markers (see also Hechter 2000). This principle underpins a wide array of phenomena under the label “nationalism”, namely attitudes, doctrines, movements, and organizational patterns of the world. Second, Gellner emphasizes that the assumption of this principle has as a consequence a strong concern about the congruence in ethno-cultural traits between the rulers and the ruled. Therefore, one important dimension of nationalism as an attitude is a negative orientation towards any actor considered to be alien to the “nation” – at least, to the extent that such an actor seeks to intervene in the political realm. When Tamir (1993) and Miller (1995) refer to something they call “liberal nationalism” or “nationality”, they seem to be referring to a different principle. This is because, albeit they praise a sense of belonging together, they would probably dislike 7 that citizens mistrusted cultural minorities, foreigners and other countries while being uncritical towards their own “nation”. Rather than to nationalism as defined by Gellner, they seem to refer to a sense of “national identification”, which other would willingly call “patriotism” (e.g. Habermas, 1996). To be certain, Miller (1995) seems to be clear enough that his “nationality” is culturally specific (Abizadeh, 2002), but one could be prone to think that this is not Tamir’s case (1993). A second term that may require some definition is that of ideological identification. The concepts of “left” and “right” supply a structure to the systems of political orientations in Europe.2 They synthesize the tension between conflicting values in European societies while integrating a wide number of issues. Inglehart (1990: 320) admits that, while the main, basic meaning of the left/right dimension “consists on whether one supports or opposes social change in an equalitarian direction”, his study reveals that this dimension tends to assimilate most important issues in the long term. In spite of the crisis of these concepts in their traditional meaning, this dimension still has full effect, as new values and interests integrate into it. Whereas ideological identification in terms of left and right is a rather vague and generic conceptualization, it is very useful in practical terms. The labels allow the diverse political actors to find one’s way about within the wideness and complexity of the political universe. They fulfill cognitive and affective functions in the understanding and evaluation of actors and policies (Sani 1974; Sani and Sartori 1983). For Sani and Montero, in Spain the individual “perceives the terms as if they were related to her/his own value system and, directly or indirectly, with her/his own position on the [left-right] continuum.” Even though those identifying themselves with the same position on a left/right axis may differ in some aspects of their political orientations and general social values, there are empirical reasons to believe that the agreement – i.e. what they share – prevails. For these authors, the left-right scale is like a “mirror” of sorts, a mirror that “necessarily reflects an oversimplified and partly distorted image, yet an image that reveals some interesting aspects of voters’ political composition” (Sani and Montero 1986: 180-181, our translation). 2 For the concept of structure in mass belief systems, see Converse (1964), Benedicto (1989) and Dalton (2005). 8 Against the historical backdrop, it is difficult to attach nationalism to either the label of “right” or the label “left”. There are instances of nationalism related to both radical (i.e. left-liberal) party families and to conservative party families (Beyme 1986; Ware 1996). During World War I there was a strong tendency within the socialdemocratic family invoking internationalism and hence opposing any conflagration between nations. Yet in the end some social-democratic parties broke the internationalist tradition and embraced nationalist allegiances. In turn, communist (and post-communist) parties have often joined nationalist movements – in particular, but not only, in developing countries during the decolonization phase. Nationalism can be found in left and right parties and nationalism can refer to overarching political systems (“state nationalism”) as well as to minority nationalisms – whether they are secessionist or come to terms with some sort of minority territorial self-government. Hence it is an empirical open question whether some nationalisms are more inclined to the left or to the right both in political labeling and discourse and in specific attitudes of solidarity and support for policies that help to change society in an equalitarian direction – namely, re-distributive policies. Data and results The data analysed here stem from the Spanish contribution to the international research project “Citizenship after the Nation-State?” (CANS), with the support of the European Science Foundation and the national governments of Austria, Germany and Spain, and different regional public agencies of Bretagne, Ille de France (France), Scotland and Wales (United Kingdom). The aim of the international study is to analyze hypothetical shifts of citizens’ public engagement and solidarity from the state level to the regional level. Nevertheless, some of the survey indicators analyzed here are specific for Spain. According to the research design for the transnational analyses, the inquiry comprises a variety of regions selected according to the strength of regional identity, regional institutional authority and regional economic wealth. The regions selected for Spain are Catalonia, Galicia and Castile-La Mancha. Catalonia is a “usual suspect”, well-know for the strength of its regional identity and self-government institutions and its relative economic affluence as compared to the Spanish average. Galicia and Castile-La Mancha, in turn, are two of the less rich regions in the country but differ from each other in that the former has a relatively 9 strong distinctive identity while the latter is representative of the mainstream Spanish identity. The survey, carried out through computed-assisted telephone interviews (CATI), includes adult citizens as well as a proportional share of international migrants that reside in the regions. The fieldwork was carried out in May 2009. In the next pages we present, in a somewhat sketchy form, different data about national identification, ideology and solidarity in the three regions under study. We will start by looking at simple cross-tabs that show the frequencies in each region of the variables used as indicators of national identification. We will proceed with an analysis of the relationship between national identification and ideology, and we will finish the analyses by looking at the relationship between national identification and some variables that can serve as proxy for economic solidarity. Relative identifications (with Spain and the region) (bi-polar scale) In Spain there is a three-decades long tradition of measuring national identification with a bi-polar scale, which was first used in 1979 and later has travelled to other countries. In a context with rival nationalisms (e.g. Catalan vs. Spanish nationalism), this instrument aims at tapping which national referent citizens feel their primary loyalties go with.3 The predispositions towards two objects potentially or actually conflictive with each other are explicitly opposed and hence we can label this “relative identifications.” Offering the same scale than most previous inquiries, in the CANS context it reads: Q5. Were you to choose, which of the following sentences best expresses how do you feel? 3 - I feel Spanish only - I feel more Spanish than Basque/Catalan/Galician This question was first used in 1979 by the opinion poll company DATA, S.A. in the Basque Country, Catalonia and Galicia (see Lint et al. 1981, 1986; Shabad and Gunther 1982) and since then has been administrated lots of times by the Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas and other research teams in Spain (for the DATA and CIS series, see Martínez-Herrera 2002). Luis Moreno (1986, 1988) introduced this in the United Kingdom and later it has been applied in Belgium and Canada and, in the context of the international project CANS, in regions of Austria, France and Germany. 10 - I feel as much Spanish as Basque/Catalan/Galician - I feel more Basque/Catalan/Galician than Spanish - I feel Basque/Catalan/Galician only Table 1. Relative identifications with the region and Spain (bi-polar scales) by region CastillaLa Mancha Cataluña Galicia Total Me siento únicamente catalán/castellano-manchego/gallego 1,8 15,7 5,6 7,6 Me siento más catalán/castellanomanchego/gallego que españo 5,0 29,4 25,1 19,8 Me siento tan catalán/castellanomanchego/gallego como españ 53,0 39,2 57,7 50,1 Me siento más español que catalán/castellano-manchego/galleg 17,5 6,4 6,1 10,0 Me siento únicamente español 20,8 6,7 3,5 10,3 No sabe 0,9 0,7 0,9 0,8 No contesta 1,0 2,0 1,0 1,3 (n) 878 865 888 2631 As we can see in Table 1, Catalonia is the region where more people identify themselves more with their region than with Spain at large – 45% of Catalonia citizens feel “only Catalan” or “more Catalan than Spanish.” This percentage is 31% in Galicia and 7% in Castile-La Mancha. It is worth to note, however, it is not Catalonia but Galicia where less people feel “only Spanish”, and that in the three regions the largest percentages are found in the option “as much as Catalan/Castilian-Manchego/Galician as Spanish.” Intensity of identifications (mono-polar scales) Contestation of a national community is not the same that the intensity of the attachment to another one – the relative identifications scale bears the problem that it may well mix people strongly rejecting one denomination with people strongly attaching to the other one, without these two things being necessarily complementary. For this reason, we also analyze the results of scales tapping the intensity of the identification with every geographical denomination separately – i.e. mono-polar scales. The scales of intensity of identification with Spain and with the region stem from these questions: 11 Q31a. Todos nos sentimos más o menos ligados al lugar donde vivimos, pero muchos nos sentimos más ligados a unos ámbitos que a otros. Usando una escala del 0 al 10, en la que 0 significa que Ud. se siente “muy poco identificado” y 10 que se siente “muy identificado”, ¿en qué medida se siente Ud. identificado con [Cataluña/Castilla-La Mancha/Galicia]? Q31b. ¿Y en qué medida se siente Ud. identificado con España? Table 2. Intensity of identification (mono-polar scales) with the region and Spain. Means comparison by region. Scales 0-10 Castilla La Mancha Cataluña Galicia Regional identification 7.18 8.11 8.39 National identification 8.18 5.88 7.50 Table 2 shows the sample means on the mono-polar scales of intensity of the identification with the country and the region. All differences are statistically significant. The majority of those living in Castile-La Mancha, Catalonia and Galicia feel identified both with their region and with Spain. Galicia is the region where people show the strongest identification with their region (8,4), and Castile-La Mancha is the area where this scores the lowest (7,2). Identification with Spain is more extensive in Castile-La Mancha and less so in Catalonia. Castile-La Mancha is also the region with the strongest score for intensity of Spanish identification (8,2). Even though Galicia leads the ranking of regional identification, it is worth it to note that this is not translated into a low identification with the country as a whole. The Galician case illustrates that the intensity of identification can measure regional nationalism as much as an ordinary sense of attachment to the region of birth or residence, without consequences for the loyalty to the Spanish political community. Hence, in the case of regional nationalism, we need to differentiate Catalan or Galician national identification from a rather apolitical sense of attachment to the region. For this reason, in some models we have introduced an interaction term with which we distinguish the strength of attachment of those that consider that Catalonia or Galicia are 12 nations in their own right from those that label them as regions.4 The interaction term is based on the following question: Q32. Which term do you prefer to describe [Catalonia/Galicia]? - A nation - A region - Neither/Other Relationship between national identification and ideological identification The association between frequency of religious practice and left-right identification in Spain is well-known. Religiosity (or its absence) is the most important predictor of individuals’ self-placement on a left-right continuum (e.g. Díez-Medrano et al., 1989; Montero and Torcal, 1995). In our models, it is the variable that yields the strongest effects on this identification. However, the main findings from the models in Table 3 concern national identification. For one thing, relative identifications attain statistically significant effects in all three regions. As individuals express to feel more strongly their Spanish allegiance than the regional one, they also tend to feel more inclined to the right than to the left. Next we turn to intensity of identifications with each collective reference. As far as intensity of Spanish identification is concerned, we find statistically significant coefficients in all three regions. The sign of the association is always positive, which means that as people express a stronger Spanish identification they tend to lean more towards the right than towards the left. As said above, for identification with the autonomous region we devise an interaction between this identification and the perception of the autonomous region as either a nation or as a region. This is to help us distinguish between minority nationalism and ordinary regional identification. The interaction term attains significant coefficients in Catalonia and Galicia, with negative signs that mean that Catalan and Galician nationalists tend to perceive themselves as 4 As our research moves ahead, we will include this interaction in all relevant models. We apologize for this draft not covering all of them yet. 13 leaning more towards the left than toward the right [This Table has to be revised as to include the interaction term]. Table 3. Ideological identification. OLS regression models. Castilla La Mancha. Regresión lineal Dep: IDEOLOGIA Modelo 1 RELIGIOSIDAD SEXO EDAD ESTUDIOS PARADO IDENTIDAD NAC. IDENTIF. CCAA IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons (n) Prob > F R2 Adj R2 .4076254 *** .1468794 -.000705 -.0334186 -.3673279 .2263875 * Modelo 2 Modelo 3 .4152841 *** .0683702 -.0004773 -.0080126 -.3355935 .4002843 *** .0723548 -.0013663 -.001771 -.3111956 -.0007314 2,869 741,000 0.0000 0.1088 0.1015 3,641 762,000 0.0000 0.1017 0.0946 .0870594* 2,971 763,000 0.0000 0.1087 0.1016 Cataluña. Regresión lineal Dep: IDEOLOGIA Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 .4388664 *** -.0028743 .0032221 -0,129 .090482 .3840663 *** -.0380168 .0003731 -.0614817 .0122005 RELIGIOSIDAD SEXO EDAD ESTUDIOS PARADO IDENTIDAD NAC. IDENTIF. CCAA IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons (n) Prob > F R2 Adj R2 .3667616 *** -.0048772 .0028841 -.0484788 .1034527 .5841108 *** -0,090 * 1,954 760,000 0.0000 0.1611 0.1544 4,293 802,000 0.0000 0.0996 0.0928 14 .1754633 *** 2,626 801,000 0.0000 0.1505 0.1441 Galicia. Regresión lineal Dep: IDEOLOGIA Modelo 1 RELIGIOSIDAD SEXO EDAD ESTUDIOS PARADO IDENTIDAD NAC. IDENTIF. CCAA IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons (n) Prob > F R2 Adj R2 .4229312 *** .0370192 .0003468 -0,129 * .0357911 .5261603 *** Modelo 2 Modelo 3 .4628119 *** .0756801 .0027199 -0,137 * .0494733 .424658 *** -.0163065 -.0049973 -.1163638 .062865 -.0284381 2,424 743,000 0.0000 0.1290 0.1219 3,845 761,000 0.0000 0.0976 0.0904 .2023437 *** 2,627 759,000 0.0000 0.1344 0.1275 * P>Z < 0.05 ** p>Z < 0.005 *** P>Z < 0.005 In a nutshell, our data show that as people identify themselves more strongly with the Spanish nation, they tend to identify themselves also with the right rather than with the left. Conversely, people identifying themselves more strongly with Catalonia and Galicia and seeing them as nations rather than regions, tend to identify themselves more with the left rather than with the right. Nevertheless, as argued above, individuals’ self-perceptions as progressive or conservative may well be flawed by their understandings of social desirability concerning these political labels. Because of this, we shall also test more specific attitudes of solidarity in different instances of support to redistribution. [Elaborate comments further] Relationship between national identification and various measures of economic solidarity Solidarity to people in need 33a. ¿En qué porcentaje estaría Vd. dispuesto a aumentar los impuestos que Vd. o su familia pagan actualmente para mejorar la atención a personas necesitadas? Por ejemplo, personas sin techo, discapacitados, ancianos y el tercer mundo. 15 First of all, there is no statistically significant difference in solidarity towards people in need across the three regions at the aggregate level, a result that casts doubts about the existence of a relationship between national identity and economic solidarity. It is worth it to highlight, in particular, that Catalans show about the same disposition to increase their taxes than Castilian-Manchegos and Galicians. Table 4. Increasing interviewee’s taxes to help people in need. Means comparison by region. Mean Std. Err. (n) Castilla-La Mancha 11,4 16,4 770 Cataluña 10,2 16,0 799 Galicia 11,3 20,0 826 Total 11,0 17,6 2394 Eta2 0,00 Comunidad Autónoma ns In order to study in depth the relationship between national identification and disposition to increase taxation to help people in need, we built linear regression models with Q33a as dependent variable, and several other as independents: sex, age, education, ideology (1-10), unemployed vs. in work, and three different measures of national identification (Model 1: relative national identification; Model 2: identification with CCAA; Model 3: identification with Spain). We run different models for each region, what leaves us with the nine regression models presented in Table 5. Results of these models show that relative identifications do not attain significant coefficients in any region. Identification with the region only yields a significant effect in Castile-La Mancha, which happens to be negative – i.e. the more identified with this region, the less ready to increase personal or family contributions to help people in need. In turn, intensity of identification with Spain only yields a significant effect in the same region, which is negative again. Thus national identifications turn out to be either irrelevant or even counterproductive when solidarity towards people in need such as homeless, handicapped, elder and developing countries is at stake. As a matter of fact, the variables that best predict this solidarity inclination are age, the level of studies and ideological identification. Young people are more prone to rise taxes than the old. As expected, left-wing people show more solidarity than right16 wing people. In addition, interestingly enough, people with the lowest educational attainments in Castile-La Mancha and Catalonia show more inclination to increase taxes than those with higher levels of education. Although this could be due to the actual effect of education, this rather suggests a relationship with family income and property and social class – in this analysis, education seems to work as a proxy to family wealth.5 Table 5. Increasing interviewee’s taxes to help people in need. OLS regression models. CASTILLA LA MANCHA. REGRESIÓN LINEAL. Dep: ¿Más impuestos? Modelo 1 Modelo 2 SEXO EDAD ESTUDIOS IDEOLOGIA PARADO IDENTIDAD NACIONAL IDENTIF, CCAA IDENTIF, ESPAÑA _cons (n) Prob > F R2 Adj R2 5 1,8046 -0,1489 *** -0,7977 -0,3763 -1,5250 0,6034 Modelo 3 1,4277 -0,1331 *** -1,0304 * -0,3663 -0,5109 1,3734 -0,1316 *** -0,7911 -0,3091 -0,2215 -0,8031 *** 17,8567 662 0,001 0,0337 0,0249 26,2763 679 0 0,0464 0,0379 -0,8656 *** 26,5117 677 0 0,0451 0,0366 From sociological research in Spain during the 1980s and 1990s, we know that education tends to correlate with left-right identification when controlling by income. We also know that, at the same time, education and income tend to correlate moderately. The CANS questionnaire, however, does not include any question on income as to isolate this from educational attainments. Hence our interpretation that formal education is working here as a proxy to family affluence. 17 CATALUÑA Dep: ¿Más impuestos? Modelo 1 SEXO EDAD ESTUDIOS IDEOLOGIA PARADO IDENTIDAD NACIONAL IDENTIF, CCAA IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons (n) Prob > F R2 Adj R2 2,2920 -0,1119 *** -0,9447 * -0,6865 * 0,1103 0,0298 Modelo 3 2,0679 -0,1129 *** -1,1104 * -0,7329 * 0,2264 2,1015 -0,1125 *** -1,1625 * -0,6643 * 0,3500 -0,0082 18,6480 696 0,0024 0,0291 0,0206 GALICIA Dep: ¿Más impuestos? Modelo 1 SEXO EDAD ESTUDIOS IDEOLOGIA PARADO IDENTIDAD NACIONAL IDENTIF, CCAA IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons (n) Prob > F R2 Adj R2 Modelo 2 -2,1317 -0,1703 *** -0,0111 -0,6049 -1,6099 0,0057 19,9760 730 0,0008 0,0312 0,0231 Modelo 2 -0,1650 20,6607 730 0,0006 0,032 0,024 Modelo 3 -2,0476 -0,1660 *** 0,0497 -0,5930 -1,4546 -1,9223 -0,1562 *** 0,0195 -0,5383 -1,5316 0,0187 25,3932 699 0,0004 0,0353 0,0269 24,5805 716 0,0004 0,0337 0,0255 -0,2800 26,0484 715 0,0003 0,0348 0,0266 Interregional Solidarity In all three regions, a large majority of citizens favours policies that re-distribute wealth from poorer to richer areas: 95% of those living in Castile, 91% in Galicia and 71% in Catalonia “agree” or “strongly agree” with the statement: Q28. Money should be transferred from the richer parts of Spain to the poorer parts to ensure that everyone can have similar levels of public services.6 6 The Spanish questionnaire reads: “Debería transferirse dinero desde las zonas más ricas de España a las más pobres para asegurar que todo el mundo pueda tener niveles similares de servicios públicos.” 18 A related statement, not referring to public services but just to redistribution (Question 27), attracts a similar level of support. 94% respondents in Castile-La Mancha, 90% in Galicia and 74% in Catalonia “agree” or “strongly agree” with: Q27. The Spanish government should step in to even out economic differences between the different parts of Spain.7 The similarity of the answers to both questions seems to indicate the existence of a consistent and cross-regional support to a certain degree of territorial redistribution through the State. We have to point out that this support, though extensive in all three regions, is higher in Castile and Galicia and lower in Catalonia. Table 6. Agreement with direct statements about solidarity between different parts of the country Money should be transferred from richer parts to poorer parts of Spain to ensure similar public services Q28 Castilla La Mancha Cataluña Galicia Muy de acuerdo 56.22 29.56 52.22 Bastante de acuerdo 35.00 37.78 33.89 Bastante en desacuerdo 3.78 20.56 5.89 Muy en desacuerdo 0.89 8.11 3.11 Ns/Nc 4.11 4.00 4.89 Total 900 900 900 7 The Spanish questionnaire reads: “El gobierno de España debería intervenir para reducir las diferencias entre los distintos territorios de España.” 19 Government to even out economic differences between different parts of Spain Q27 Castilla La Mancha Cataluña Galicia Muy de acuerdo 53.06 31.98 53.21 Bastante de acuerdo 40.92 41.83 36.94 Bastante en desacuerdo 4.39 17.38 6.65 Muy en desacuerdo 1.62 8.81 3.21 (n) 865 863 842 Cramer's V = 0.1973 gamma = 0.0269 ASE= 0.026 In order to measure to what extent national identification and regional solidarity are associated, we have built ordinal logistic regression models with Q28 as dependent variable, and several other as independents: sex, age, education, ideology (1-10), unemployed vs. in work, and three different measures of national identification (Model 1: relative national identifications; Model 2: identification with CCAA; Model 3: identification with Spain). We run different models for each region, which leaves us with the nine regression models presented in Table 7. The bi-polar scale on relative identifications yields a statistically significant effect in Catalonia and Galicia: a mayor identidad regional en detrimento de la española es menor el apoyo a transferir dinero desde las zonas más ricas a las más pobres de España para que todos tengan unos servicios públicos similares. Este efecto es especialmente pronunciado en Cataluña. En Castilla La Mancha la identidad nacional no tiene efectos sobre el deseo de realizar dichas transferencias entre territorios. Si sustituimos en el modelo las relative identifications por la intensidad de la “identificación con la CCAA” podemos ver que esta variable sólo muestra efecto en Cataluña, donde quienes más se identifican con Cataluña, más en contra están de las transferencias entre CCAA. Finalmente, si incluimos en los modelos la intensidad de la “identificación con España”, encontramos que esta variable únicamente se asocia significativamente con la solidaridad interregional en Cataluña y Galicia. En ambos casos, quienes más se identifican con España son más favorables a reducir las diferencias entre territorios. La relación es más fuerte en Cataluña que en Galicia, como viene siendo habitual en los 20 anteriores modelos de regresión. Con todo, no deja de ser llamativo que en una región de inequívoca lealtad española como es Castilla-La Mancha ningún indicador de identificación nacional tenga capacidad predictiva con respecto a la solidaridad interterritorial. Cabe señalar que en Castilla La Mancha dos variables correlacionan con la solidaridad territorial: la edad y los estudios. En ambos casos la relación es positiva: a mayor edad o más estudios, más apoyo a la solidaridad territorial. En Cataluña y Galicia estas variables no arrojan efectos significativos. It is also worth mentioning that left-right identification only predicts support for this type of redistribution in one out of nine models. This is interesting as it suggests that, for many people, the fact of not being supportive to solidarity between territories does not prevent them to feel they are on the left – nor the other way around either. Hence it seems that for them, generally, solidarity between different parts of the same country does not belong to their understanding of the concepts left and right. This can look surprising if considering that, during the last three decades at least, the mainstream parties of the Spanish left and center-left have considered transfers from the most economically developed areas of the country to the less developed ones to be part and parcel of social justice.8 However, the explanation can also lie in the rhetoric of the parties in the center-right and the right. While the Basque and, especially, the Catalan center-right parties opposed the doctrine of evening out economic differences between regions, the Spanish-wide conservatives tended to accept it to the extent that the financial transfers were sent to regions governed by them, such as Galicia.9 8 In special, the Izquierda Unida (United Left) of Julio Anguita and the social-democratic party (PSOE) of Felipe González. 9 However, the state-wide conservatives tended to criticize subsidies to the long-duration countryside unemployed in Andalusia and Extremadura, both regions being ruled by the social-democrats. 21 Table 7. Money should be transferred from richer parts to poorer parts of Spain to ensure similar public services. Ordinal logit regression. CASTILLA LA MANCHA. REGRESIONES ORDINALES. SOLID. (P28) Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 Coef. Coef. Coef. REGIONAL SEXO -.2141533 -.1574812 -.1804644 EDAD -.0152937** -.0145375** -.0143178** ESTUDIOS -.1365468* -.1207529* -.1169202* IDEOLOGIA -.0375952 -.0432627 -.0448914 PARADO .2914976 .245187 .2394766 IDENTIDAD NAC. .0301109 IDENTIF. CCAA -.0048325 IDENTIF. ESPAÑA Number of obs. LR chi2(6) Prob > chi2 Pseudo R2 .0278383 Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 723 19.09 0.004 0.0158 744 17.28 0.0083 0.0137 745 16.93 0.0095 0.0134 CATALUÑA. REGRESIONES ORDINALES. Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 SOLID. REGIONAL Coef. Coef. Coef. SEXO .0300877 -.0493185 .0174587 EDAD -.0109553* -.0131663*** -.0073842 ESTUDIOS .0430013 .1236082* .0526693 IDEOLOGIA .0141444 -.0698366* -.0153899 PARADO -.3271494 -.2876028 -.3671617 IDENTIDAD NAC. -.647615*** IDENTIF. CCAA .2402958*** IDENTIF. ESPAÑA Number of obs. LR chi2(6) Prob > chi2 Pseudo R2 -.1837277*** Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 739 101.37 0.0000 0.0537 780 73.20 0.0000 0.0368 779 84.47 0.0000 0.0425 22 GALICIA. REGRESIONES ORDINALES. Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 SOLID. REGIONAL Coef. Coef. Coef. SEXO .2334918 .1877797 .243642 EDAD -.0075357 -.0084196 -.0059431 ESTUDIOS -.0119901 -.0052851 -.0097907 IDEOLOGIA -.0090536 -.0345877 -.0181022 PARADO .1275225 .0661187 .0613862 IDENTIDAD NAC. -.2031408* IDENTIF. CCAA -.0489964 IDENTIF. ESPAÑA -.0891863** Modelo 1 Number of obs. 726 LR chi2(6) 12.29 Prob > chi2 0.0557 Pseudo R2 0.0086 * P>Z < 0.05 ** p>Z < 0.005 *** P>Z < 0.005 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 745 10.38 0.1095 0.0071 743 16.10 0.0132 0.0110 Regresión lineal con INPUESTOSREST como dependiente 33b. (Si P33a <>0) Y de esta cantidad, ¿qué porcentajes le gustaría que se destinasen a personas necesitadas de su municipio, de Galicia, de España, de Europa y del resto del mundo? 33c. (Si P33a =0) Y de los impuestos que usted ya está pagando, ¿qué porcentajes le gustaría que se destinasen a personas necesitadas de su municipio, de Galicia, de España, de Europa y del resto del mundo? In order to analyse the preferred area for allocating tax money we have build a new variable named “Impuestosrest”. This variable indicates whether the interviewee wants to see the tax money spent principally on his/her region, or in Spain at large. The range of values of this variable goes from -100 (100% of taxes should be spent on the interviewee’s region) to 100 (100% of taxes should be spent on Spain as a whole). A value of 0 indicates that the interviewee wants 50% of tax money spent in his/her region and the other 50% in Spain. As we can see in the following table, mean values for this variable are negative for Catalonia and Galicia and positive for Castile-La Mancha. This means that citizens of Castile-La Mancha tend to prefer a distribution of tax money that benefit all Spanish territories, while citizens of Catalonia and Galicia prioritise their own regions. DEPENDIENTE: IMPUESTOSREST = [(%Impuestos a España-%Impuestos a la CCAA)/( (%Impuestos a España+%Impuestos a la CCAA)]x100 23 Comparación de medias. Distribución del dinero recaudado vía impuestos Rango (virtual) de la variable: -100/100. -100 = el 100% de los impuestos recaudados en la CA deben gastarse en la CA; 100 = el 100% de los impuestos deben gastarse en el resto de España; 0 = 50% a la CA y 50% al resto de España.[i1] CCAA Mean Std. Err. [95% Conf. Interval] Castilla La Mancha Cataluña Galicia 2,15 -2,07 -1,45 1,26 1,49 1,30 -0,33 -2,36 -1,70 4,62 -1,78 -1,19 Linear regression models with Q33b/c as dependent variable and the same independent variables included in previous models (Table 8) confirm most of the findings about inter-territorial solidarity. Intensity of Spanish identification remains unable to predict this solidarity in Castile-La Mancha. In one model for support for inter-territorial transfers in Catalonia, people identified with the right support interregional transfers the most. These findings suggest two things. For one, if anything, inter-territorial transfers seem to be a policy supported by the right rather than by the left. Spanish national identification solely increases the probability of support for solidarity across territories in regions in which it is challenged by rival national projects. 24 Table 8. Difference in assistance to regional and statewide people’s in need. OLS regression. CASTILLA LA MANCHA. REGR. LINEAL Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 Coef. Coef. Coef. SEXO -2.542.036 -1.421.453 -2.862352 EDAD -.1663923 -.1595051 -.1720667* IMPUESTOSR~T ESTUDIOS .6992608 .4635496 1.059175 IDEOLOGIA 1.110066 1.3528* 1.270772* PARADO -2.497401 -3.228474 -3.262957 IDENTIDAD .NAC 3.312978* IDENTIF. CCAA -1.905714*** IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons .3962822 -5.513.301 1.755.294 1.644.672 Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 Number of obs 627 644 643 Prob > F = 0.0149 = 0.0003 = 0.0447 R-squared = 0.0251 = 0.0387 = 0.0200 Adj R-squared = 0.0156 = 0.0296 = 0.0108 CATALUÑA. REGR. LINEAL IMPUESTOSR~T Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 Coef. Coef. Coef. SEXO -.646032 .0900252 -.7585033 EDAD -.1169243 .0028474 -.1562014 ESTUDIOS -1.87126 -3.652.992*** -1.53063 IDEOLOGIA .7257474 2.469.557*** .8061398 1.61319 1.649.642 1.060912 PARADO IDENTIDAD NAC. 16.8641*** IDENTIF. CCAA -5.31072*** IDENTIF. ESPAÑA _cons 5.778.053*** -54.66699 Modelo 1 Number of obs 24.10772 Modelo 2 -44.4796 Modelo 3 661 693 693 Prob > F = 0.0000 = 0.0000 = 0.0000 R-squared = 0.1894 = 0.1040 = 0.1871 Adj R-squared = 0.1820 = 0.0962 = 0.1800 25 GALICIA. REGR. LINEAL IMPUESTOSR~T Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 Coef. Coef. Coef. SEXO -3.123567 -2.114.833 -2.406.194 EDAD .0250856 .1464995 .0366581 ESTUDIOS .5202302 .2900946 .4834794 IDEOLOGIA .2450658 .8101761 .4112595 -1.222239 -1.163.807 -.8867832 PARADO IDENTIDAD NAC. 8.227.056*** IDENTIF. CCAA -3.273301*** INDENTIF. ESP 1.216911* _cons -36.2465 5.382.293 -24.24533 Modelo 1 Modelo 2 Modelo 3 Number of obs 632 651 649 Prob > F = 0.0005 = 0.0002 = 0.3190 R-squared = 0.0374 = 0.0406 = 0.0108 Adj R-squared = 0.0282 = 0.0317 = 0.0016 * P>Z < 0.05 ** p>Z < 0.005 *** P>Z < 0.005 Discussion and conclusions Many hopes have been pinned on national identification since the 19th century, not only by ordinary citizens but also by political elites who have suffused their discourse with ubiquitous invocations to national feelings. More recently, during the last decade and a half, a number of political theorists have advanced a sophisticated and attractive combination of nationalism and liberalism. One of their most appealing arguments is the suggestion that national identification – as a product of nationalism – helps secure or regain citizens’ solidarity inclinations – in particular, their support for redistribution policies and the welfare state. Since this claim is widely extended but seldom proved, this study has tested empirically it as a falsifiable scientific hypothesis. Previous research showed that it was untenable for British national identity. The current piece of research shows that is also untenable for Spanish national identity, for Catalan national identity and for Galician national identity. In Castile-La Mancha, Galicia and Catalonia alike a large majority of citizens favour policies that re-distribute wealth from poorer to richer areas. Yet as a matter of fact, Spanish national identification only has a significant positive impact on support for territorial transfers in 26 regions in which rival nationalist projects are on extant – namely, Catalonia and Galicia. In turn, Catalan and Galician national identifications only predict reluctance to solidarity between richer and poorer territories and a preference for supporting their local people in need rather than people in need in Spain at large. Interestingly enough, this is so in spite of Galicia qualifying as a poor region vis-à-vis the Spanish average. Furthermore, Catalan and Galician nationalists tend to see themselves as leaning to the left rather than to the right, while the opposite holds for Spanish nationalists. This lends credence to the view that Spanish nationalism remains associated to conservative and traditional political values, parties and political leadership more than thirty years after the end of Franco’s regime and its Spanish nationalist rhetoric and paraphernalia. However, when respondents are asked about their inclination to increase their taxes in order to aid people in need, the expectation of redistributive generosity of people who feel stronger their national identity becomes doubtful. Ideological identification, together with class and age, is the variable that best predicts solidarity toward people in need. Conversely, measured through different indicators and referring to the different “nations”, national identifications turn out to be either irrelevant or even counterproductive. Therefore, as it came up in the case of British nationalism, the theory does not hold for Spanish national identification. In addition, it is dubious for Catalan and Galician minority nationalisms. If we are to found the sources of solidarity, including support for re-distributive policies, social research should rather look elsewhere – the most plausible candidates being the values of universalism and human equality. References Abizadeh, A. (2002) Does liberal democracy presuppose a cultural nation? American Political Science Review, 96 (3), 495-509. Benedicto, Jorge. 1989. “Sistemas de valores y pautas de cultura política predominantes en la sociedad española (1076-1985)”, in Tezanos et al. La transición democrática española. Madrid: Sistema. Beyme, Klaus von. 1986. Los partidos políticos en las democracias occidentales. Madrid: Siglo XXI. Brubaker, R.; F. Cooper (2000) Beyond ‘identity’. Theory and Society, 29 (1), 1-47. 27 Converse, Philip E. 1964. The nature of belief systems in mass publics. Pp. 206-61 in David E. Apter (ed.) Ideology and discontent. NewYork (NY): Free Press. Dahl, R. (1989) Democracy and Its Critics. New Haven: Yale Univ. Press. Dalton, R.J. (2005) Citizen Politics. Public Opinion and Political Parties in Advanced Industrial Democracies [4th ed.]. Chatham (NJ): Chatham House. Díez Medrano, Juan; Blanca García-Mon; Juan Díez Nicolás. 1989. El significado de ser de izquierdas en la España actual. Revista Española de Investigaciones Sociológicas, 45: 9-41. Gellner, E. (1983) Nations and Nationalism. Oxford: Blackwell. Habermas, J. (1996) ‘The European nation-state – its achievements and limits’ in G. Balakrishnan (ed.) Mapping the Nation. London: Verso, pp. 281-94. Hechter, M. (1987) ‘Nationalism as group solidarity’, Ethnic and Racial Studies,10 (4), 415426. Hechter, M. (2000) Containing Nationalism. New York: Oxford Univ. Press. Hobsbawm, E.J. (1992) Nations and Nationalism since 1780. Programme, Myth, Reality. [2nd ed.] Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. Inglehart, R. (1990) Cultural Shift in Advanced Industrial Society. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. ---- (1997) Modernization and postmodernization. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. Keating, M. (2001) Nations Against the State. The New Politics of Nationalism in Quebec, Catalonia and Scotland. Hampshire: Macmillan. Linz, J.J; M. Gómez-Reino; F. Orizo; D. Vila. 1981. ‘Cataluña: nacionalismo autonomista y política de clase.’ Pp. 540-564 in Informe sociológico sobre el cambio político en España, 1975-1981. Madrid: FOESSA-Euramérica. ----. 1986. Conflicto en Euskadi. Madrid: Espasa-Calpe. Martínez-Herrera, E. (2002) ‘From nation-building to building identification with political communities. Consequences of political decentralization in Spain, the Basque Country, Catalonia and Galicia, 1978-2001.’ European Journal of Political Research 41(4): 42153. ---- (2004) ‘Liberal-nationalist theory, political confidence and support for the welfare state. Evidence from Britain’. EUI Working Paper SPS 2004/8. Florence: European University Institute. 28 ---- (2009) ‘The unbearable lightness of British liberal nationalism,’ in P. Karolewski and A. Suszycki (eds.) Nationalism in Contemporary Europe. Lantham (MD): Lexington (forthcoming) McEwen, N. (2002) ‘State welfare nationalism: the territorial impact of welfare state development in Scotland’. Regional and Federal Studies, 12 (1), 66-90. Miller, D. (1995) On Nationality. Oxford: Clarendon Press. ---- (1996) ‘On nationality’, Nations and Nationalism, 2, 409-21. Montero, J.R.; M. Torcal (1995) ‘Cambio cultural, conflictos políticos y política en España’. Revista de Estudios Políticos, 89: 9-34. Moreno, L. (1986) Decentralisation in Britain and Spain: The Cases of Scotland and Catalonia. Ph.D. thesis. University of Edinburgh. ---- (1988) Scotland and Catalonia: the path to home rule. Pp. 166-181 in David McCrone and Alice Brown, eds. The Scottish government yearbook. Edinburgh: Unit for the Study of Government in Scotland. ----; McEwen, N. (2005) ‘Exploring the territorial politics of welfare’ in N. McEwen and L. Moreno, eds. The Territorial Politics of Welfare. Oxon/New York: Routledge, pp. 1-40. Parekh, B. (2002) ‘Being British.’ Government and Opposition, 37 (3), 301-15. Putnam, R.D. (1993) Making Democracy Work. Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. ---- (2000) Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster. Sani, G.; J.R. Montero (1986) ‘El espectro político: izquierda, derecha y centro’. In J.J. Linz and J.R. Montero (eds.) Crisis y cambio: electores y partidos en la España de los años 80. Madrid: Centro de Estudios Constitucionales. Sani, G. (1974) ‘A test of the least-distance model of voting choice: Italy, 1972’. Comparative Political Studies 7. Sani, G.; G. Sartori (1983) ‘Polarization, fragmentation and competition in Western democracies’. Pp. 307-340 in Hans Daalder and Peter Mair, eds. Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change. Beverly Hills (CA): Sage. Shabad, G.; R. Gunther (1982) ‘Language, nationalism and political conflict in Spain.’ Comparative Politics 14(4): 443-477. Tamir, Y. (1993) Liberal nationalism. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. 29 Taylor, C. (1996) ‘Why democracy needs patriotism’ in M.C. Nussbaum and J. Cohen (eds.) For love of country. Debating the Limits of Patriotism. Boston: Beacon Press, pp. 119-21. Ware, Alan (1996) Parties and Parties Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 30