04 Richard Mattessich, A concise history of analytical acc…

Anuncio
123
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
A CONCISE HISTORY OF ANALYTICAL ACCOUNTING:
EXAMINING THE USE OF MATHEMATICAL NOTIONS IN OUR
DISCIPLINE1
Richard Mattessich
RESUMEN
Este trabajo ofrece una sucinta revisión de los métodos de matemática analítica empleados en teneduría de
libros y contabilidad durante los últimos cinco milenios. Sin embargo, el énfasis se centra en la segunda mitad del
siglo XX, en el cual el uso de ideas matemáticas, de conceptos formales y de técnicas es cuando verdaderamente
floreció. Aparte de un uso creciente del interés compuesto y de los cálculos del valor actual, las últimas se refinaron
grandemente con la introducción de variables probabilísticas, de modelos estocásticos, de errores en términos
estadísticos (como se encuentran, por ejemplo, en la versión ampliada y perfeccionada de la clean surplus theory).
Pero este período (de los últimos 50 años más o menos) comenzó propiamente con modelos contables deterministas
(que han probado su valor práctico últimamente en el desarrollo de hojas de cálculo electrónicas y sistemas
presupuestarios). Hubo asimismo mucha experimentación con álgebra lineal y no lineal (incluyendo el álgebra
matricial) y otras técnicas de investigación operativa, así como en métodos de muestreo estadístico contable que han
probado su utilidad particularmente en la auditoría. Con todo, el logro intelectual culminante fue el lento pero
impactante desarrollo de las posibilidades de información (information perspective) ofrecidas por la contabilidad
(incluyendo información económica, la perfeccionada versión de la clean surplus theory y la teoría matemática de la
agencia. Estos esfuerzos han sido resumidos recientemente en la obra en dos volúmenes de Christensen y Feltham
(2003, 2005).
ABSTRACT
The paper offers a succinct survey of analytical-mathematical methods as employed in bookkeeping and
accounting during some five millennia. However, the emphasis is on the second half of the 20th century where the
1
The author gratefully acknowledges financial support by the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of
Canada for this project as well as the use of academic facilities by the Sauder School of Business of the University
of British Columbia. This is a somewhat expanded version of a paper presented in May 2005 in Cracow at the
International Conference for General Accounting Theory III. I express my gratitude to Prof. Mieczeslaw Dobija,
for permission to publish this material in De Computis.
The paper offers merely a concise survey that includes only the most important pertinent publications. It also
interprets “analytical accounting” more in the modern sense of relating it to mathematics (hence the Subtitle) rather
than in the broader sense of logical reasoning in general—though occasionally such extension could not be
avoided. However, this interpretation is much broader than that in Wagenhofer (2004) where it is restricted mainly
to what in our paper is discussed in Section 4 (information perspective). Furthermore, the expression “analytical
accounting” in English must not be confused with the French comptabilité analytique , the Italian contabilitá
analìtica, or the Spanish contabilidad analítica, all of which used to refer to cost accounting.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
124
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
use of mathematical ideas, formal concepts and techniques truly flourished. Apart from an increasing use of
compound interest and present value calculations, the latter have been greatly refined by introducing
probabilistic variables and stochastic models, statistical error terms, etc. (e.g., as encountered in a refinement
and extension of the clean surplus theory). But this period (of the last 50 years or so) began rather with deterministic
accounting models (that ultimately proved of practical value in the development of computerized spreadsheets and
budgeting systems). There also was much experimentation with linear and non-linear algebra (including matrix
algebra) and other operation research techniques, as well as with statistical sampling methods for accounting that
proved particularly useful in auditing. Yet the crowning intellectual achievement was the slow but impressive
development of the “information perspective” of accounting (including information economics, the refined clean
surplus theory and mathematical agency theory). These efforts were recently summarized in the two -volume work by
Christensen and Feltham (2003, 2005).
PALABRAS CLAVE:
Historia de la contabilidad analítica, uso de nociones matemáticas, álgebra matricial, information perspectiva,
clean surplus theory, teoría matemática de la agencia
KEY WORDS:
History of analytical accounting, use of mathematical notions, matrix algebra, information perspective, clean
surplus theory, mathematical agency theory
1. Introduction
The relation between mathematics and bookkeeping or accounting is ancient;2 after all,
accounting uses numbers to represent aspects of reality, and it was no lesser than Pythagoras who
told us that the universe is written in numbers. So it is hardly surprising that the first published
treatise on “double-entry” (“Particularis de computis et scripturis”) appeared in a book on
mathematics. I refer, of course to Luca Pacioli’s (1494) famous Summa de Arithmetica,
geometria, proportioni et proportionalita (Part I, Section 9, Treatise 11).3 But this dependence
2
The following quote from Moonitz and Jordan (1963, p. 5) not only offers a distinction between bookkeeping and
accounting, but also hints at the intimate relation of analytical procedures to accounting: “Historically, doubleentry bookkeeping has developed as a method by which the economic activities of privately owned and operated
business concerns are recorded. Accounting, by contrast, may be viewed as the group of analytical techniques by
which the financial aspects of economic activities are examined, evaluated and cast into the mould of double -entry
bookkeeping. These analytical techniques consist, in the main, of a body of postulates and procedures, whether
logical or conventional in nature, and provide a powerful tool by which an orderly, systematic representation of the
complex activities of economic entities may be obtained [my italics].” In this paper, however, we often tend to
associate analytical methods with mathematical techniques--though, precisely speaking, analytical methods
transgress such a narrow definition.
3
Pacioli’s work must not be confused with the “first treatise on bookkeeping”. Apart from Leonardo da Pisa’s (i.e.
Fibonacci’s) Liber abaci (1202) and probably some preceding Arab texts (cf. Antoni, 1996), a much earlier
manuscript on accounting (containing such sophisticated ideas as purchasing power fluctuations) can be found in
several sections of Kautilia’s Arthasastra (ca. 300 B.C.) from India —see, Mattessich (2000, pp. 131-149).
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
125
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
was by no means a one-way street. Already centuries before Pacioli, accounting contributed
essentially to mathematics itself (see Colebrooke 1817/1973, as well as Mattessich 1998, and
2000, pp. 153-145) by giving Indian mathematicians (like Brahamagupta of the 7th century and
Bha skara of the 12th century) the idea and justification of using not only positive but also
negative numbers. They considered debt claims (or debits) as positive items and liabilities (or
credits) as negative claims, and thus were the first to conceive negative numerals as legitimate
notions of mathematics (hundreds of years before the Europeans recognized them as such). And
millennia before that, the Sumerians established a “token system” of accounting that not only
proved to be the precursor of writing but also of abstract counting (cf. Mattessich 2000, pp. 4569).
But for centuries the major mathematical aspects of accounting were limited to arithmetic.
It was mainly in the 19th century that algebra was employed to express more general accounting
relations. This constituted a revolution that may be difficult to comprehend by modern
accountants. The differences between these algebraic relations may seem to us so simplistic that
they bordered on the trivial. Yet, Accountants of the 19th century hardly thought so. The evidence
lies in the many “theories of accounts classes” and the controversies that followed in their wake.
Many an author tried to prove that his classification scheme was better than the others or even the
only correct one (for details see Mattessich 2003, particularly pp. 129-131). Usually these
schemes were presented in simple algebraic equations, each one a variation or re-arrangement of
the equilibrium equation (and from a mathematical point of view usually equivalent to the
others), expressing that the value of all assets (or debits) equals the value of all equities (credits).
Let me give you an illustration: If one author pleaded for the equation “Assets = Liabilities +
Owner’s Equity”, while his opponents argued in favour of the mathematically equivalent relation
of “Assets – Liabilities = Owner’s Equity”, intending to emphasize a different kind of
classification, an extra-mathematical element was introduced that a mathematician may find
trivial (as for him the two equations are equivalent).
Occasionally, however, more sophisticated ideas entered commercial and accounting
thought. One of the first of those notions was the one of compound interest. According to
Chatfield (1996a, p. 145) it was already known to the Babylonians between 1600 B.C and 1800
B.C., and was later found by Leonardo da Pisa (1202) as well as by Pacioli (1494). Other related
notions were the discounting of debts and the “present value method”. According to Schneider
(1981, p. 76) this approach was established by Leibniz in 1682 as a by-product of juridical
reflections on the premature repayment of debts (cf. collected works of Leibniz, ed. by Gerhard,
1962/1863)--let us call this “PV Phase I”. But it appears that it was Stevin (1582)—also deemed
to be the inventor of the “income statement”--who was “the first to apply the net present value
approach to financial investments” (cf. Chatfield 1996b, p. 208) as well as the annuity method
(cf. Volmer 1996, p. 565).4 Seicht (1970, pp. 341-348, 511-547) points out that the application of
the present value approach in accounting (and the kapitaltheoretische Bilanz) played an important
4
According to Parker (1959: 35), it was Jean (Jan) Trenchant (1558) who first used “interest tables” and “discussed
geometric progressions and compound interest.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
126
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
role in the German Railway Statutes of 1863 and subsequent legislations. At any rate, the entire
complex of present value calculations proved to be not only crucial for finance and investment
theory but, ultimately, held its sway over accountants and accounting scholars.
In the nineteenth century the present value and compound interest calculations
were important in the insurance business. In the early 20th century, Ciompa (1910), Kempin
(1910), Zappa (1920-29), Heina (1925) and Rieger (1928) also seem to have favoured some form
of the present value approach to accounting. And the major extensions of the present value method
in the 20th century were numerous. They reached from the formulations of Canning (1929) and
particularly of Preinreich (see next Sub-Section) to numerous uses in financial and managerial
accounting (from tax and depreciation formulas to compound interest for debts and investments
as well as goodwill). These efforts were finally crowned by the sophisticated revisions of the
clean surplus theory, as executed by Ohlson (1995) and Feltham and Ohlson (1995, 1996) with
the incorporation of stochastic variables (for details see Sub-Section 4.3).
Other original mathematical contributions to the 19th century theory of accounting
were those by August de Morgan and Giovanni Rossi. De Morgan (1846) was the first to
introduce an accounting matrix, and Rossi (1889) offered in his book on “the double-entry
chessboard” dozens of examples in which accounting matrices played a decisive role, though
neither he nor de Morgan used matrix algebra (conceived by Cayley in 1858—see Cayley, 19891897). But Rossi did suggest that the accounting matrix (lo scacchiere a schede, as he called ti)
could be converted into a sophisticated computing device. This might be regarded as anticipating
the computerized spreadsheet--though Rossi, like Charles Babbage [1791-1871] the inventor of
the first ‘digital’ computer, had a mechanical instead of an electronic device in mind. At any rate,
if Stevin and Leibniz were the starting points of present value accounting, Rossi pointed at the
future of computerized accounting spreadsheets, both of which developed into important
branches of mathematical accounting during the 20th century.
2. Mathematical refinements in the first half of the 20 th century
Beyond the classificational-algebraic schemes of the 19th and early 20th century, the
impact of inflation and current value accounting (after World War I), particularly in Austria,
Germany and France (though also in America by Sweeney) helped to improve algebraic thinking
in accounting—though systematic mathematical models were rarely used.
Surprisingly, during the first half of the 20th century the present value (discount) method
was by no means readily accepted for accounting purposes. Even such an “academic giant” as
Schmalenbach rejected it for statement presentation; he admitted “present values” only for the
evaluation of firms in special cases (e.g., assessments, liquidations), but only outside the balance
sheet. However, some voices of the time were in favour of employing present values in
accounting (we might call this “PV Phase II”). One of the first of those voices was that of
Canning (1929) who—stimulated by Irving Fisher’s (1906) use of accounting statements as
illustrations for his economic theory—recommended present values for accounting purposes. In
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
127
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Italy it was Zappa (1937) who saw the problem of income measurement as inseparable from the
problem of measuring changes in the present value of capital. But a more sophisticated and
mathematical use of the present value approach was made by Preinreich (e.g., 1933, 1936a,
1936b, 1937a, 1937b, 1938, 1939, 1996) in a series of highly original publications that were not
only neglected at the time, but literally fell into oblivion until they were slowly rediscovered
towards the end of the century (see Brief and Owen 1973; Peasnell 1982, Brief 1996; Brief and
Peasnell 1996). Indeed, Gabriel Preinreich may be considered the founding father of modern
analytical accounting (including the first phase of the clean surplus theory: CST Phase I). His
models were designed for depreciation, amortization and investment purposes, based on
compound interest, annuity and present value calculations. They analysed such phenomena as
“good will” and the “clean surplus”.
Apart from the present value approach, there were geometrical as well as algebraic
formulations of different versions of the break -even chart, though most of these contributions
came from engineers (just as the major contributions to the present value approach derived from
economists). The first version of the break-even chart was presented by the German-American
engineer Henry Hess [1864-1922] in Hess (1903). Almost at the same time, and independently
from Hess, the Scotch chartered accountant Sir John Mann [1863-1955] presented in Mann
(1903-07, and particularly in 1904) the same idea. Subsequently, and apparently also
independently from their predecessors or even each other, the notion of a break-even chart was
introduced by the American engineers C. E. Knoeppel (1920, 1933), linking this graph to flexible
budgeting, Walter Rautenstrauch [1880-1951] in Rautenstrauch (1922), christening this graph as
“break-even chart”, and John H. Williams (1922), using not only geometric but also algebraic
means to explain various relations of break-even and budgeting analysis (cf. Parker, 1969: 7071). Such an algebraic analysis can also be found in Rautenstrauch (1930, 1932) and Arthur J.
Minor (1930).
3. Analytical Accounting in the Second Half of the 20 th Century
The second half of the 20th century introduced a great variety of mathematical approaches
and techniques to accounting. First, I shall continue (in 3.1) with the further development and
employment of present values in accounting (PV Phase III). Second, there was a widespread use
of accounting matrices (that led to computerized spreadsheets) and the application of matrix
algebra to accounting theory and practice, particularly in cost and managerial accounting (see 3.2
and 3.5). Third, attempts to axiomatize accounting used set-theoretical and similar mathematical
devices to attain rigorous formulations of accounting principles (see 3.3). Fourth, statistical
methods (particularly sampling techniques) were introduced to accounting and auditing, and
proved (particularly in the latter area) spectacularly successful. Also techniques of statistical
hypothesis testing were widely applied in empirical and behavioural accounting theory and, last
but not least, operations research models, particularly such techniques as goal-programming,
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
128
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
exercised some influence in cost accounting (see 3.4). Related to this are some improvements of
the break-event analysis (e.g., Jaedicke, 1961; Charnes et al., 1963).
Out of the concern with accounting matrices arose the idea of building models for
computerized budgeting and electronic spreadsheets (see 3.5). Finally, set-theoretical as well as
stochastic models were constructed to apply information economics (in the narrow sense),
mathematical agency theory, refinements of the clean surplus theory, and similar subjects related
to accounting (see 3.6). The last area may, from an intellectual point of view, have been the most
exciting achievement. It is for this reason that I have devoted to its further development an entire
section (4). Finally, Section 5 is devoted to the conclusion with some speculation about future
analytical accounting developments.
3.1 More widespread enthusiasm for present values
During the second half of the century the influence of economics and the emergence of
“finance” (as a subject independent of accounting) gave a decisive boost to the further
exploration of the present value approach for accounting (including statement presentation). In
Continental Europe, Honko (1959) from Finland, Hansen (1962) from Denmark, and Käfer
(1962) from Switzerland were among the first who continued to explore this line of research.
Later, followed relevant research by Horst Albach (1965) and others in Germany, and Gerhard
Seicht (1970) in Austria.
The synthetic balance sheet theory of Albach (1965) and the capital-theoretic balance sheet
theory of Seicht (1970a, pp. 558-619) are both based on the present value approach. Albach’s (1965)
theory is a synthesis of two methods: (1) the valuation of individual assets (regarded as past
expenditures) at acquisition costs; and (2) the valuation of owners equity regarded as future
(expected) receipts (based on the firm’s budget) and discounted at the internal profit rate (interner
Zinsfuß). In this way the balance sheet became a control instrument for determining the rate at which
the firm’s budget was on course.
Seicht (1970) was opposed to this approach. His capital-theoretic balance sheet theory was
claimed to be even more strongly oriented towards the future as he abandoned the acquisition cost
basis for the purpose of asset valuation. In his notion the firm’s assets were stated at the discounted
future receipts. Correspondingly, the firm’s debts were based on the discounted future expenditures,
and the owners equity (but now based on acquisition costs) became equated to the discounted future
capital re-payments (for details, refer to the original). Here too the discount rate was the internal
interest or profit rate (instead of the opportunity cost rate or riskless interest rate used in the more
recent American literature). It is interesting to note that in this approach “the sum total of all periodic
profits always amounted to the total profit of all periods” (Seicht, 1970, p. 560, translated). This
would make Seicht a defender of the clean surplus theory.
In the English accounting literature, the American paper by Alexander (1948) became
widely known for its promotion of the present value approach, and so did the paper by Corbin
(1962). Furthermore, textbooks, like Moonitz and Jordan (1963) incorporated discussions of
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
129
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
discount and present value methods (e.g., for valuation, depreciation, and other purposes). The
famous book by Edwards and Bell (1961)--better known for its excellent presentation of the
nominal and real versions of the current (i.e., replacement) value method--also took the present
value approach into consideration.5 Gordon (1960) and Peasnell (1982) took up Preinreich’s
(1996—posthumous collection) ideas and developed them into the theory of clean surplus (CST
Phase II). The major breakthrough in this area, however, came with a series of publications by
Ohlson, Feltham and others--to be dealt with separately as CST Phase III (see Sub-Section 4.1).
3.2 Accounting matrices and matrix algebra
As we have seen in Section 1, accounting matrices were already known in the 19th
century, but matrix algebra seems to have been used first in macro-accounting by Leontief (1951)
and later by Fuerst (1955), then in cost accounting by two Germans, Pichler (1953) and Wenke
(1956, 1959), and in general accounting theory by Mattessich (1957, 1964a).
Subsequently, a flood of pertinent publications in the application of matrix algebra, linear
and non-linear programming and other mathematical techniques appeared (e.g., Rosenblatt, 1957,
1960); and some fifty of those publications have been collected in Williams and Griffin (1967).
Among the books in this area the following must be emphasized: Ijiri’s (1965a) dissertation on
goal-oriented models, and the publications by Williams and Griffin (1964) and Corcoran (1968)
both on mathematical applications in accounting. Furthermore, one might mention two other books.
First, the Japanese translation of a collection of papers by several North American authors
(Corcoran, Goetz, Mattessich, and Richards) edited by Koshimura (1969) under the translated title
Contributions to matrix accounting. And second, a Brazilian work by Florentino (1965) under the
translated title Mathematical foundations of accounting and its educational application to
programming and bookkeeping analysis. Later books on matrix accounting were those by Shank
(1972) and the doctoral thesis by E. C. Smith (1974).
3.3 Attempts to axiomatize accounting
In the 1950s and early 1960s analytical accounting took a new direction. It concerned
attempts to axiomatize accounting theory that arose out of the dissatisfaction with the traditional
framework of accounting rules and loosely connected principles. This was preceded by Aukrust’s
(1955) attempt to axiomatize national income accounting. At a time when related disciplines
(such as economics, finance, operations research, etc.) reached for more sophisticated
mathematical methods and tools, young scholars felt the need for a more analytical and
systematic approach in the construction of a conceptual framework of business accounting. This
5
Edwards and Bell (1961) also helped to promote algebraic thoughts in accounting, although the book did not
present those models of inflation and current value accounting in a comprehensive mathematical scheme —for
such a model or family of models, see Mattessich (1995, pp. 97-124).
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
130
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
direction was actually pursued by two groups that partly competed, partly cooperated with each
other. The first “postulational” direction (preceded by one of the chapters in Paton, 1922, and a
paper by Sweeney, 1937) hardly qualifies as a “mathematical-analytical” approach as it avoided
mathematical concepts. The other “axiomatic” direction followed a more rigorous methodology
with clear assumptions, mathematical theorems and corresponding proofs (yet, in comparison to
the more recent trend of stochastic-analytical accounting, those earlier applications of
mathematical concepts were deterministic and relatively moderate—though, nevertheless, heavily
attacked, at the time, as “too sophisticated”).
The first camp (Moonitz, 1961; Sprouse and Moonitz, 1962; Study Group of the
University of Illinois, 1964, Givens, 1966) got its impetus from Chambers (1955, 1957, 1966),
while the second one (Winborne, 1962, and Ijiri 1965b, 1967, 1971, 1975) may have been
stimulated by the experiments in Mattessich (1957, 1964a). Such publications as Zeff (1982),
Slaymaker (1996) and others indicate that some of those endeavours may ultimately have
influenced the FASB (Financial Accounting Standards Board, 1978 and subsequent pertinent
publications) and led to its conceptual framework and similar attempts. However, this conceptual
framework was occasionally criticized (e.g., Archer, 1993) and its limited academic success may
well be attributed to the fact that the foundations of such conceptual frameworks were not
formulated rigorously enough. On the other hand, a mathematical and axiomatic accounting
framework was premature at a time when practitioners were not even ready for the much less
demanding mathematics of inflation accounting (cf. Mattessich, 1995, p. 97).
On a purely theoretical level, the second (i.e., mathematical) camp influenced a wide
range of scholars in North America as well as abroad in examining, in a fairly rigorous way, the
foundations of accounting. In Germany, these efforts included a German version (Mattessich
1970) of Accounting and analytical methods, as well as axiomatization attempts by Kosiol (1970,
1978) and Schweitzer (1970, 1972), both using the pagatoric (i.e., cash-flow) basis. The approach
of these two authors was criticized by Schneider (1973) for paying insufficient attention to
purpose-orientation (Zwecksetzung) and to the valuation problem. Indeed, in this neglect lies the
decisive difference between the postulational or axiomatic attempts of Kosiol and Schweitzer,
that is not explicitly purpose-oriented, and that by Mattessich (1964a, 1970) which has such an
orientation. In Australia this search for an axiomatic basis was continued by Wells (1971, 1976),
and in Japan by Saito (1972, 1973) with a response by Mattessich (1973).
In the late 1970s this trend was resumed in America and Great Britain as, for example, in
a doctoral dissertation by Orbach (1978) and a paper by Tippett (1978). In Italy a similar interest
was manifested in Onida (1970) and Galassi (1978), and in the Spanish language area pertinent
publications were those by García-García (1972), Requena-Rodríguez (1972), and BuenosCampos (1974).
Axiomatization and related analytical efforts continued even into the 1980s, 1990s and
beyond, though by that time this area no longer occupied centre-stage. In America it was
Carleson and Lamb (1981) as well as Mattessich (1995: Chapter 5); in England Willett (1985,
1987, 1988), Gutiérrez (1990, 1992), Gutiérrez and Whittington (1997); in Germany Herde (1992),
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
131
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Balzer and Mattessich (1991, 2000); in the Latin-American countries, Ávila et al. (1988) and Sá
(1995); in Japan, Harada (1978), Deguchi and Nakano (1986) as well as Koguchi (1990). The
latter author found further applications of this methodology in situations of macro- and mesoaccounting that refer primarily to more local environmental accounting issues (apart from his
translation of Balzer and Mattessich, 1991, into Japanese in 1994).
3.4 Sampling techniques, hypothesis testing, econometrics, and OR
The application of statistical sampling methods to accounting and, particularly, to auditing
(audit risk models) has become one of the most successful mathematical tools of the public
accounting profession. Sadly enough, its pioneer Laurence Vance (1950) is hardly ever
mentioned (he is neither profiled in the encyclopeadic work of Chatfield and Vangermeersch,
1996, nor even listed in its lengthy entry on “Statistical Sampling“ by Tucker, 1996)—and this
despite the fact that some years later he published in co-authorship a more “popular” version as a
textbook (see Vance and Neter, 1956). Yet his work seems to have been eclipsed by more
sophisticated sampling techniques as presented in such texts as Trueblood and Cyert (1954),
Trueblood and Cooper (1955), Cyert and Trueblood (1957), Stringer (1961), Arkin (1984) and
others6 —or in research papers like Ijiri and Kaplan (1971).
To those efforts might be added the innumerable empirical accounting publications
employing hypotheses testing and other statistical techniques that are indispensable for this kind
of direction. However, to list here even a few representative examples would be hardly
appropriate as it would transgress the confines of a survey on analytical accounting. Though it is
correct that the foundations of statistical hypotheses testing are still mathematical, hence
‘analytical’, the application of these tools (whether in accounting or elsewhere) is the contrary,
namely ‘inductive-empirical’. Something similar may hold for the econometric studies of cost
behaviour by managerial economists like Dean (1948, 1951, 1954) or Johnston (1960) that are no
less inductive-empirical. And as to the promising achievements of empirical accounting research,
the latter is likely to attain its full long-run potential only if based on sound analytical models.
Among the Operations Research techniques applied to accounting, particularly to cost
accounting, the best example is the two-volume work on goal-programming by Charnes and
Cooper (1957, 1961), and Charnes et al. (1963), though some parts of these works might have to be
regarded as management model building in a more general sense.
6
Books on sampling techniques for auditing and accounting have meanwhile become numerous. A recent listing in
the WorldCat (internet subscription for libraries) showed no less than 75 books.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
132
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
3.5 Mathematical accounting models for computer programmes
Another area where the expression “analytical” may be more controversial than that of
“mathematical” is the application of computerized spreadsheets to business accounting. The first
suggestion of an electronic spreadsheet seems to have been in my paper on budgeting models and
system simulation (Mattessich, 1961). The subsequent elaboration of this idea consisted in
presenting as a prototype a mathematical budget model of an entire firm in Mattessich (1964a) as
well as a complete computer program in Mattessich (1964b). The latter was supplemented by a
computer output of some 48 computerized spreadsheets (with sub-budgets for cash flows, labour
costs, material costs, purchases, sales, overhead expenses with proper allocations, as well as a
projected income statement and balance sheet). That this was the first electronic spreadsheet (in
FORTRAN IV for mainframe computers) and the forerunner of such best-selling spreadsheet
programmes (for personal computers) of the 1980s, such as VisiCalc, SuperCalc, Lotus 1-2-3,
and Excel, is acknowledged by MacHaney’s (2000) article in the Encyclopedia of computers and
computer history, vol. II, as well as in other encyclopedic works (see Murphy, 1996), and
documented in detail by Mattessich and Galassi (2000).
Apart from electronic spreadsheets, computers have played a long-standing role in
accounting, as manifested in such books as McRae (1964) and Li (1968) as well as the many
articles of the journal Computers in Accounting (1984-1993). In the 1990s related model building
led to attempts of introducing expert systems to accounting and finance—see, for example,
Thierauf (1990), O’Leary (1992), Brown and Wensley (1995).
3.6 The beginning of information economics in accounting
The veritable pioneer of the application of information economics to accounting is G. A.
Feltham (1967) with his Berkeley doctoral dissertation and subsequent works (e.g., Feltham,
1968, 1972). Joel Demski, inspired by Feltham (both then at Stanford University) soon joined
forces with him in such significant publications as Feltham and Demski (1970) and Demski and
Feltham (1972, 1976, 1978) that earned them jointly the highest research award of the American
Accounting Association. Related or alternative information approaches to accounting theory (as
well as extensions to the original theory) were presented by Butterworth (1967), Lev (1969),
Mock (1969, 1971, 1976), Baiman (1975) or the information inductance approach by Prakash and
Rappaport (1977), and many others.
Information economics was originally developed by such economists as Stigler (1961,
1962), J. Marschak and Miyasawa (1968), Marschak and Radner (1972), J. Marschak (1974), and
others for the purpose of determining the economic value and consequences of information.
Feltham goes even further back in time and points out that:
The development of models of rational choice under uncertainty by such pioneers
as von Neumann and Morgenstern…can be viewed as the starting point of
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
133
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
information economics. They demonstrate that if an individual’s choice behaviour
satisfies a few rather basic “consistency” axioms, then this behaviour can be
represented as the maximization of his expected utility for the consequences of the
actions available to him. (Feltham, 1984, pp. 181-182).
Thus the roots of information economics go back to Bayesian decision and game theory as
well as the probabilistic version of the states-acts-outcome matrix, as originally conceived by
Savage (1954). The results of such a matrix can serve as a valuable basis of comparison (i.e.,
telling us what the outcome would be without additional information).7
However, in the hands of accountants the “information perspective of accounting” (as
nowadays called by Christensen and Demski, 2003) covers a much broader area. In the second
half of the 1970s, it was noticed that basic agency theory (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972;
Williamson et al., 1975; and above all, Jensen and Meckling 1976)--dealing with the contractual
relation between "principal" and "agent", various agency costs, risk-sharing and incentive
problems—offered a welcome extension of the information perspective to managerial accounting.
This resulted in what one might call "analytical agency (or contract) theory" (for detailed survey
articles, see Baiman 1984, 1991). This approach introduced a kind of rationalistic version of the
stewardship notion to our discipline and made it the central paradigm of managerial accounting
(cf., Gjesdal, 1981)—and this, despite previous attempts to elevate investment decision-making to
this pivotal role. And for an attempt to relate agency theory to ethics, see Noreen (1988)—for
further details on agency theory, see below, Sub-Section 4.2.
Soon afterwards another mathematical (and stochastic) theory, that of “clean surplus”-- as
extended by Ohlson (1987a, 1987b, 1990, 1995), Feltham and Ohlson (1995, 1996) and others -found its way into the now broad research area of the information perspective (see Sub-Section
4.1). Indeed, this field has become the dominant area of analytical accounting research. Even a
cursory survey of its present status needs to be accommodated in a separate (forth) section.
4. The present status of the information economic perspective
It took some 30 years for this branch to mature to its present status. The reason for this
long digestion period lies, partly, in the wearisome process of building the relevant mathematical
models, partly, in the meticulous work of the scholars involved in this endeavour. There exist
7
The most fundamental theorem of information theory was proven by Blackwell (1951, 1953), though “couched in
terms of experiments, but various authors have explored its implications for comparing information systems (e.g.,
Marschak and Miyasawa [1968], Marschak [1974], Marschak and Radner [1972], and McGuire [1972])” (Feltham,
1984, p. 182). Thus the value of an information system can be derived by comparing the maximized expected
utilities of such a system with that of a simple decision system (e.g., based on a probabilistic version of Savage’s
states-acts-outcome matrix). A more pragmatic way to determine this value would be to ask how much people are
willing to pay for such an information system.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
134
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
several papers that offer pertinent surveys (e.g., Feltham, 1984, Mattessich, 2005), but the best
and most comprehensive survey are the two volumes of P.O. Christensen and Feltham (2003,
2005). A less comprehensive work, intended as an introduction for graduate students to the
information perspective, is the book by J.A. Christensen and Demski (2003). Whether these
works mark a breakthrough in this field—i.e., extending the interest in this area from a relatively
small elite of specialists to a broader or even global interest in analytical accounting—still is to
be seen. But the mathematical rigor presented in these publications (particular in the work of the
two volumes by Christensen and Feltham with some 250 propositions and their mathematical
proofs) indicate that academic accounting may be on a critical threshold. It may be added that in
Germany and Austria the books by Ewert and Wagenhofer (1993/2003) and Wagenhofer and
Ewert (2003), and in Italy the one by Cilloni (2004) made strides to familiarize accountants with
information economics and its relation to our discipline.
The major items of critique advanced against this approach are, first that it is actually not
dealing with “accounting” but rather with the “economics of accounting” (as admitted in the title
of Christensen and Feltham, 2003, 2005); and second, that it is too esoteric. Indeed, most of its
literature as well as the books by Christensen and Demski (2003) and Christensen and Feltham
(2003, 2005) operate with a conceptual apparatus very alien to the average accountant and, what
may be worse, a neglect of the traditional tools used by accountants. But this hurdle may be
overcome to some extent, as proven by two German books on this subject (so far not translated
into English). The first is by Ewert and Wagenhofer (1993/2003), dealing mainly with
managerial accounting, while the second one, by Wagenhofer and Ewert (2003), concerns
financial accounting. Both publications succeeded fairly well in combining major aspects of the
information perspective with conventional accounting and, what is most important, without
throwing the accustomed vocabulary and concepts overboard.
Another argument, perhaps less valid but interesting, runs as follows: information
economics is basically concerned with determining the value of information. That is to say with
the question: How much resources ought to be spent in search of information, and when are these
costs of searching for information higher than the value of the information itself (cf. Stigler,
1961)? But it does not seem that the information perspective of accounting is applying this
maxim of minimizing information costs to its own activity. In other words: Does, perhaps, our
building of complex information models cost more than the benefits derived from it? And do we,
at all, try to answer such a question? The reason why this argument itself is controversial, is
because it refers to scientific research where such reasoning can be self-defeating.
4.1 The information perspective vs. traditional accounting
The information perspective as seen by its major pioneers has several features that
distinguish it decisively from conventional accounting. Therefore, a rapprochement or
reconciliation between these two areas may require some compromise in both quarters. And the
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
135
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
first and foremost prerequisite for this, is a clear vision of the major differences between them.
We may distinguish two such categories; the first refers to the philosophic and methodological
differences, the second to the conceptual or technical ones.
(1) While traditional accounting focuses on valuation, viewing it as a pragmatic
process that depends on the information objective, the information perspective (particularly as
pursued by Christensen and Demski, 2003) seems to reject traditional valuation as the purpose of
accounting. It rather sees the function of accounting as providing information (thereby emphasizing
the value or content of information and the underlying uncertainty that gives information its
meaning) as well as revealing where and in which way accounting information (as well as nonaccounting information) is produced. This perspective also emphasizes the distinction between
public and private information and the implications of each for financial markets.
Christensen and Feltham (2003, 2005) also stress the distinction between
accounting’s decision-facilitating role (affecting the decision maker’s beliefs about the
consequences of his actions) vs. its decision-influencing role (where anticipated accounting reports
concerning a decision maker’s actions may influence his action choices). While the former is likely
to play a more important role in financial accounting, the latter is usually more relevant in
managerial accounting (including agency theory). As to the “philosophic” issue, I believe that at a
time when our discipline has greatly expanded in many directions, it is only proper to count the
economics of accounting as an integral part of modern accounting.
(2) Whereas the information perspective employs stochastic models, statistical
expectations (expressing objective as well as subjective beliefs), formal utility functions, partitions
and sub-partitions of the state space, and other sophisticated concepts (of modern economics,
probability and decision theory, operations research, game theory, and finance theory), traditional
accounting usually disregards most of these developments. A wide variety of model types are being
used by the different branches of the information perspective, but as Wagenhofer (2004, p. 9)
points out, most “of them belong to the family of games with incomplete information. These games
are characterized as having at least two players with different information endowments and
potentially different interests. These characteristics seem to fit well with the general setting in
which accounting is embedded. The common solution concept for such games is the (Bayesian)
Nash equilibrium.”8
4.2 The modern clean surplus theory
The essence of clean surplus is easy to describe. Provided there are no contingent claims
(such as convertible debts, executive stock options) involved, this notion refers to an income
derived from a comparison of the book value of a firm’s owners equity at the beginning of the
8
A simplistic way to explain the Nash equilibrium is the example of a contractual situation in which one player A
knows that player B is cheating, but B knows that A knows it, and so on ad infinitum. So each player
accommodates himself or herself to this fact, and an equilibrium emerges.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
136
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
accounting period with the firm’s value at the end of this period (eliminating new investments or
withdrawals by the owners). It results from the "all-inclusive" income statement where the sumtotal of all the annual earnings, from the beginning of a firm (e.g., starting with cash) to its
liquidation, equals the sum-total of all annual incomes of the firm’s lifetime. This can be
expressed in the following equation (though this and the second equation are merely a highly
simplified version of the “modern clean surplus theory” as presented by Ohlson, 1995; and
Feltham and Ohlson, 1995):
1. The Clean Surplus Relation (CSR):
Book value (at t) = book value (t-1) + income (period ending at t) – dividends (at t)
In contrast to this, the conventional current operating income (or its statements) do not
provide such a "clean" surplus (or “income”), because the sum of all their annual income figures
do not necessarily add up to the firm’s life-time earnings. Those “dirty” income statements
exclude many kinds of extraordinary items (be they capital and non-operating gains or losses, or
residuals from past periods, etc.), relegating them to separate surplus statements. But this does
not lessen the respectability of such dirty income statements. Indeed, they permit income
smoothing over several accounting periods (avoiding erratically fluctuating annual income
figures) that reveal the long-term profit trend. Apart from resurrecting several pertinent insights
of Preinreich,9 Ohlson argued that only a simple notion of "pure" earnings is economically
relevant and sufficient to determine a security’s pay-off (i.e., its price plus dividend).
A second notion plays a decisive role in launching this theory. It is that of residual income
(also called “excess income” or “`abnormal earnings”), defined (under CSR) as “the net income
minus a capital charge, which equals the riskless interest rate i (i.e., start-of-period interest rate
times start-of-period book value) according to Christensen and Feltham (2003, p. 281).
2. The Residual Income Relation (RIR):
Market value (at t) = Book value (at t) + All future “residual income” discounted at rate i.
Hence residual income can be regarded as the difference between the firm’s income and
the cost of capital. This theory, together with further extensions made in Ohlson (1995) and
Feltham and Ohlson (1995, 1996), has been called (by Bernard, 1995) a “paradigm-shift” away
from the market based research of Ball and Brown (1968) as well as Beaver (1968)—yet, not
9
E.g., such a statement as: "The yield of common stocks is not dependent upon the corporate dividend policy so long
as that policy conforms to the principle of good management" (Preinreich 1936a, p. 137). This is an anticipation of
a well-known insight credited to the Nobel laureates Modigliani and Miller (1958) and Miller and Modigliani
(1961), known as "Modigliani-Miller dividends irrelevancy". Or "A fundamental truth about accounting is that,
given perfect and unlimited foresight, no matter at what value an asset is placed on the books and no matter in
what haphazard way it is amortized over its unexpired life, the discounted excess profits plus the recorded value
will always give the true fair market value, even though both the investment and the excess profits are measured
incorrectly. This statement is a simple theorem of arithmetic." (Preinreich (1937b, p. 220).
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
137
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
only towards a more analytical approach but, perhaps surprisingly, also one more in conformity
with accounting tradition. As hinted at in Section 1, this theory can be regarded as an elegant
extension (in several directions) of the present value model in determining the value of a firm and
its shares.
However, the original clean surplus relation (as shown above) still has an important
limitation. Its income or dividends referred to future expectations and not to the “past” figures of
accounting statements. To overcome this impediment, the first extension introduced by Ohlson
(1995) was to relate past figures to future expectations. He created a “linear information
dynamics” by adding to the right hand side of the residual income relation RIR (equation 2) a set
of stochastic variables and error terms that imposed a series of restrictions (e.g., risk neutrality of
investors) and linearity assumptions about the probabilistic time-series behaviour of abnormal
earnings and of information about other than abnormal earnings (e.g., innovations). This "other
information" could reflect, for example, the reports of security analysts as well as some
unpredictable random disturbances. Such a modification attempts to project accounting figures of
the past into the future. To what extent these or similar regressions will prove satisfactory has, of
course, to be tested empirically.
A second extension might be seen in “objectifying” the original subjective present value
approach of Fisher and Canning in as far as the RIR equates the present value (of all expected
residual incomes + present book value that already is “discounted”) with the market value (that is
considered objective).
Third, Ohlson and Feltham (1995) introduced into this theory a distinction between
financial and operational activities of a firm (here not shown). The latter activities are considered
an important residual, after borrowing and lending data are separated--though remaining tied to
the first by cash flows--although this distinction between financial and operational activity is
admittedly arbitrary.
Fourth, a more important distinction (introduced also by Feltham and Ohlson, 1995, 1996)
is that between unbiased accounting (based on economic valuation) and conservative accounting
(based on traditional accounting valuation). Under unbiased accounting (on average) the market
value will equal the book value; whereas under conservative accounting the market value (on
average) exceeds the book value. Both of these distinctions constitute significant steps in
bridging the gap between the information perspective and traditional accounting.10
There are, of course, many other analytical as well as empirical attempts to develop
sufficiently accurate means of predicting future earnings (for details, see Lee, 1999). After all,
such predictions are the central object of any modern value theory of the firm. But the extended
clean surplus theory of Feltham-Ohlson has, so far, been the most popular among the many
attempts. Even commercial variations of this model have been marketed under such trademarks
10
Cf. Bernard (1995, p. 733): “These studies return to issues so basic as to render them direct descendants of work
done no later than the 1960s....Ohlson (1995) and Feltham and Ohlson (1995) represent the base of a branch of
capital market research might have followed, but did not.”
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
138
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
and brand names as: Stern Stewards EVA, Hot Value Associate’s CFROI, McKinsey Economic
Profit Model, etc.
4.4 Mathematical agency theory
As pointed out above, agency theory is now a well-established part of the information
perspective (as information plays a decisive role in entering into a specific agency contract as
well as in monitoring the agent’s activity). Some experts may regard the original part of the
information perspective (plus some parts of the extended clean surplus theory) as closer to
financial accounting, while the agency part corresponds more to managerial accounting. This
seems to be reinforced by the division of the work by Christensen and Feltham (2003, 2005)
where the first volume is devoted to “information in markets”, and the second to “performance
evaluation”.
Agency theory is probably that part of the information perspective most familiar to most
accounting academics. Thus I merely recapitulate its major activities and notions. Agency theory
attempts to determine (depending on individual circumstances) the appropriate type of contract
between principal and agent (usually between owner and manager). Thereby the following
notions play an important role: first best vs. second best contracts, performance and reporting
incentives through bonus plans, stock options, etc., (requiring incentive compatibility between
both parties), performance evaluation, and asymmetry of information (often the agent has more
information than the principal). Further key notions are: the danger of deliberately supplying
misinformation, moral hazard, risk preference (e.g., risk taking by the principal vs. risk aversion
of agent), observability vs. unobservability or indirect observability of the agent’s performance,
monitoring the agent’s activity through surprise inspections or auditing activities, agency costs
(due to either employing monitoring devices or, alternatively, income loss by the principal due to
insufficient monitoring). Finally, the distinction between private vs. public information plays an
important part, as does the variety of information sources, the mixing and separation of different
information sources, earnings management (using inter-temporal accruals or income smoothing
for shifting profits from one period to another by the agent), and so on.
Depending on the particular organizational structure, these numerous notions offer a rich
pallet for designing mathematical models supposed to reflect the first-best or second-best
management contracts. The alternative combinations are large, and so are the potential model
types--for a survey of this literature, see Christensen and Feltham, 2005).
5. Summary and Conclusion
The influence of mathematics and analytical thinking on accounting has come a long
way—and I do not refer so much to the past five thousand years, rather to the last 50 years or so.
Of course, originally it may have begun with the token-envelope accounting of the Sumerians
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
139
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
with simple clay tokens (representing individual assets) and their impressions on clay envelopes
(as an inseparable representation of the corresponding equity) or with later classification
schemes. In classical and medieval times (not to forget India and the Arab world) as well as
during the Renaissance it was arithmetic that dominated the scene. From the 16th century onwards
valuation issues based on discounted debts, annuity methods and present values occasionally
touched our discipline (Stevin, Leibniz). Finally, in the 19th century algebra played an increasing
role in the teaching of bookkeeping and in conveying different classification schemes. During
this period, accountants became more interested in compound interest and present value
calculations. The notion of fluctuating prices and price levels (particularly during rampant
inflations) also led to algebraic thinking in accounting. All this opened the door to a more general
and abstract vision of our discipline during the first half of the 20th century--with scholars like
Canning promoting present values, and Preinreich pioneering pertinent model building in
accounting and finance.
But only the second half of the 20th century opened the floodgates of our
discipline to the use of higher mathematics on a broad scale. Accounting academics of this period
were not merely more receptive towards employing the present value method for statement
presentation, they also experimented with a wide variety of mathematical techniques and
concepts. Above all, this period began with attempts to axiomatize accounting in order to replace
the loose set of accounting rules or principles with a more rigorous foundation. The use of
accounting matrices and models led to increasing interest in matrix algebra as well as linear and
non-linear algebra in general. The consequence of this type of deterministic model building led
inevitably to more comprehensive accounting models that proved crucial for the development of
computerized spreadsheets and electronic budgeting. Furthermore, operations research techniques
were applied to cost and managerial accounting, and statistical sampling methods became a
highly successful tool for accounting and, particularly, for auditing practice. Other statistical
techniques, such as hypothesis testing played an indispensable role in modern empirical
accounting research—that, however, already transgresses into the area of non-analytical
accounting.
Since the late 1960s information economics played a steadily increasing role in
analytical accounting research. This application was introduced by a series of doctoral
dissertations at the University of California at Berkeley (among which that by Feltham proved to
be the most significant launching pad). Originally the determination of the value and content of
information (or of an entire information system) formed core and pivot. As time went by, and
non-mathematical agency theory came about, agency theory was “mathematized” and
incorporated into the information perspective. Finally, the clean surplus theory (particularly as
revised by Ohlson and Feltham since the mid-1990s) became an integral part of the information
perspective of accounting. At the beginning of the 21st century the advent of such graduate texts
as J. A. Christensen and Demski (2003) and P. O. Chrsistensen and Feltham (2003, 2005) in
North America, as well as the German texts by Ewert and Wagenhofer (1993/2003) and
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
140
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Wagenhofer and Ewert (2003) have summarized the major tenets of this sub-field, and made it,
hopefully, more palatable to a larger audience of academic accountants.
Although the information perspective constitutes a formidable intellectual
achievement of analytical accounting, it is not without its critiques. As it is more “economics of
accounting” (than accounting in the traditional sense), and as it requires considerable
prerequisites of mathematics, finance and economics, it is inaccessible not only to the majority of
practitioners but also to many accounting academics. Surprisingly, the two German texts (see
paragraph above) have been more successful in integrating major aspects of the information
perspective with traditional accounting than were the major American texts. The latter continued
to disregard conventional accounting terminology and made little effort to explain their insights
in a language accessible to most accountants--though it has to be emphasized that this subdiscipline aims foremost towards a general and theoretical understanding than to practical knowhow.
Attempts have been made (and are continued to be made) to factually verify some of the
analytical propositions of this sub-area. But it may be too early to assess the empirical relevance
of many of them. It still has to be seen to what extent this achievement will influence or even
determine the future of accounting as an applied and normative discipline. However, to close on a
positive note, let me quote a summary of the major aspects of analytical accounting as presented
by Wagenhofer:
The major advantage of analytical research lies in its precision and the rigor of its
analysis, its explicit assumptions, and the logic behind its results. The results can
be intersubjectively confirmed. This methodology is particularly useful for gaining
insights into situations that are characterized by the strategic interactions of
different decision-makers with information asymmetry and potentially diverging
interests. The resulting equilibria often include prima facie counterintuitive results,
and uncover important conditions that must be present for certain results to hold.
The best justification for the use of a model is if the result is surprising relative to
prior knowledge. (Wagenhofer, 2004, p. 26).
REFERENCES
Alchian, A. A. and H. Demsetz (1972): “Production, information costs, and economic organization”, American
Economic Review, December, 777-795.
Albach, Horst (1965): “Grundgedanken einer synthetischen Bilanztheorie“ (Basic thoughts to a synthetic balance
sheet theory), Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft, 35, 21-31.
Alexander, Sydney S. (1948): “Income measurement in a dynamic economy”, Contribution of the Study Group on
Business Income, AICPA (reprinted in Five Monographs on Business Income , New Yo rk, NY: Study Group
on Business Income, American Institute of Accountants, 1950; and in a modified version in W. T. Baxter
and S. Davidson, eds., Studies in Accounting Theory, London, 1962, 126-217).
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
141
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Antoni, Tito (1996): “Leonardo de Pisa” (Leonardo Pisano) (Fibonacci 11??-12??), in M. Chatfield and R.
Vangermeersch, eds., The history of accounting—An international encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland
Publishing, Inc., 377-379.
Archer, Simon (1993): “On the methodology of constructing a conceptual framework for financial accounting”, in
Michael J. Mumford and Kenneth V. Peasnell, eds., Philosophical Perspectives on Accounting --Essays in
Honour of Edward Stamp, London, UK: Routledge, 1993, 62-122 (see also Accounting, Business and
Financial History 2, September 1992 and March 1993, 199-228 and, 81-108 respectively).
Arkin, Herbert (1984): Handbook of sampling for auditing and accounting, New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Aukrust, Odd (1955): Nationalregnskap -Teoretske Prinsipper
principles). Oslo: Statistik Centralburå.
(National income accounting—Theoretical
Ávila, H.E., G. Bravo and E.R. Scarano (1988): An axiomatic foundation of accounting, Working Paper, Buenos
Aires: Institute of Accounting Research, University of Buenos Aires.
Baiman, Stanley (1975): “The evaluation and choice of internal information systems within a multiperson world”,
Journal of Accounting Research, 13, Spring, 1-15.
Baiman, Stanley (1984): “Agency research in managerial accounting: A survey”, in R. Mattessich, ed., Modern
Accounting Research: History, Survey, and Guide, Vancouver, BC: Canadian Certified General
Accountants’ Research Foundation, 251-294 (Originally published in the Journal of Accounting Literature,
1, Spring 1982, 154-213).
Baiman, Stanley (1991): ·Agency research in managerial accounting: A second look”, in R. Mattessich, ed.,
Accounting research in the 1980s and its future relevance (and its French translation--see Preface),
Canadian Certified General Accountants’ Research Foundation, 221-256 (originally published in
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 15, 1990, 341-371).
Balzer, Wolfgang and Richard Mattessich (1991): “An axiomatic basis of accounting: A structuralist approach”,
Theory and Decision, 30, 213-243. (Japanese translation by Y. Koguchi), Keizaigaku Ronsan, 35, May
1994, 209-232).
Balzer, Wolfgang and Richard Mattessich (2000): “Formalizing the basis of accounting”, in W. Balzer, J. D.
Sneed, and C. U. Moulines, eds., Structuralist Knowledge Representation—Paradigmatic Examples,
Amsterdam: Rodopi, Atlanta GA (Vol. 75 of the Poznan Studies in the Philosophy of the Sciences and
Humanities), 99-126.
Bernard, Victor (1996): “The Feltham-Ohlson framework: Implications for empiricists”, Contemporary Accounting
Research, 11, Spring, 733-147.
Blackwell, D. (1951): “Comparison of experiments”, Proceedings of the Second Berkeley symposium on
Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 93-102.
Blackwell, D. (1953): “Equivalent comparison of experiments”, Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 24, 267-272.
Brief, Richard B., ed. (see also under Preinreich) (1996): A Landmark in Accounting Theory: The work of Gabriel
A. D. Preinreich, New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
142
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Brief, Richard B. and Joel Owen (1973), “Present value models and the multi-asset problem”, The Accounting
Review, 48, October 1973, 690-695.
Brief, Richard B. and Kenneth V. Peasnell, eds. (1996): Clean surplus, a link between accounting and finance,
New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc.
Brown, Carol E. and Anthony K. Wensley (1995): Expert systems in accounting, auditing, and finance: Special
Issue, New York, NY: Pergamon.
Buenos Campos, E. (1974): Los sistemas de información en la empresa (Information systems of the firm), Madrid:
Confederación Española de Cajas de Ahorro.
Butterworth, John E. (1967): Accounting systems and management decision: An analysis of the role of information
in the managerial decision process, Berkeley, CA: Doctoral dissertation, University of California.
Canning, John B. (1929): Economics of Accountancy, a Critical Analysis of Accounting Theory, New York, NY:
Ronald Press.
Carlson, Marvin L. and James W. Lamb (1981): “Constructing a theory of
The Accounting Review, 56, July, 554-573.
accounting--An axiomatic approach”,
Cayley, Arthur (1989-1897): The collected mathematical papers of Arthur Cayley, Cambridge, UK: The University
Press.
Chambers, Raymond J. (1955): “Blueprint for a theory of accounting”, Accounting Research, 6, January, 17-25.
Chambers, Raymond J. (1957): “ Detail for a blueprint”, The Accounting Review, 32, April, 206-215.
Chambers, Raymond J. (1966): Accounting, evaluation and economic behaviour, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: PrenticeHall, Inc. (reprinted in Accounting Classics Series, Houston, TX: Scholars Books Co., 1975).
Charnes, Abraham and William W. Cooper (1957): “Management models and industrial applications of linear
programming”, Management Science , 4, October, 38-91.
Charnes, A. and W. W. Cooper (1961): Management models and industrial applications of linear programming, 2
vols., New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Charnes, Abraham, William W. Cooper and Yuji Ijiri (1963): “Breakeven budgeting and programming to goals”,
Journal of Accounting Research, 1, 1, Spring, 16-41.
Chatfield, Michael (1996a): “Compound interest”, in M. Chatfield and R. Vangermeersch, eds., The history of
accounting: An international encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland Publisjing, Inc.: 145.
Chatfield, Michael (1996b): “Discounted cash flow”, in M. Chatfield and R. Vangermeersch, eds., The history of
accounting: An international encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland Publisjing, Inc., 208.
Chatfield, Michael and Richard Vangermeersch, eds. (1996); The history of accounting: An international
encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
143
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Christensen, John A. and Joel Demski (2003): Accounting Theory--An Information Content Perspective, New
York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Christensen, Peter O., and Feltham, G. A. (2003): Economics of Accounting; Volume I: Informa tion in Markets.
Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Christensen, Peter O., and Feltham, G. A. (2005): Economics of Accounting; Volume II: Performance Evaluation
(forthcoming), Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Cilloni, Andrea (2004): Economia dell’ informazione e sistemi contabili aziendali (Information economics and
business accounting systems), Milan: Dott. A. Giuffrè Editore.
Ciompa, Pawel (1910): Grundrisse einer Ökonometrie und die auf der Nationalökonomie aufgebaute natürliche
Theorie der Buchhaltung (Outlines of an `econometrics’ and a natural theory of bookkeeping based on
macro-economics), Lemberg: Poeschel Verlag.
Colebrooke, Henry T. (1817/1973). Algebra with arithmetic and mensuration from Sanskrit of Brahmegupta and
Bháscara, London: John Murray (reprinted in Wiesbaden: Martin Sändig, 1973).
Corcoran, A. Wayne (1968): Mathematical applications in accounting, New York, NY: Harcourt, Brace and
World, Inc.
Corbin, Donald A. (1962): “The revolution in accounting”, The Accounting Review, 37, October, 626-635.
Cyert, Richard M. and Robert M. Trueblood (1957): Sampling techniques in accounting, New York, NY:
Prentice-Hall, Inc.
Dean, Joel (1948): “Cost structures of enterprises and break-even charts”, American Economic Review, March, 153164.
Dean, Joel (1951): Managerial economics, New York, NY: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
Dean, Joel (1954): “Measurement of real economic earnings of a machinery manufacturer”, The Accounting Review,
29, April, 255-266.
Deguchi, H. and B. Nakano (1986): “Axiomatic foundations of vector accounting”, Systems Research, 3, 1, 31-39.
De Morgan, August (1846): Elements of arithmetic, 5th ed., London, U.K.: Taylor and Walton, 1846 (translation
into Japanese and Chinese, Ekawa-Matchi: Shizukoa Shugakujo, 1872).
Demski, Joel S. and Gerald A. Feltham (1972): “Forecast evaluation”, The Accounting Review , 47, July, 533-548.
Demski, Joel S. and Gerald A. Feltham (1976): Cost determination--A conceptual approach, Ames, IO: Iowa State
University Press.
Demski, Joel S. and Gerald A. Feltham (1978): “Economic incentives in budgetary control systems”, The
Accounting Review , 53, April, 336-359.
De Pisa, Leonardo (1202): Liber abaci, Pisa.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
144
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Edwards, Edgar O. and Philip W. Bell (1961): The Theory and Measurement of Business Income, Berkeley, CA:
University of California Press.
Ewert, Ralph. and Alfred Wagenhofer, A. (1993/2003): Interne Unternehmensrechnung (Managerial accounting),
Berlin: Springer Verlag (5th edition: 2003).
Feltham, Gerald A. (1967): A theoretical framework for evaluating changes in accounting information for
managerial decisions (doctoral dissertation), Berkeley, CA: University of California.
Feltham, Gerald A. (1968): “The value of information”, The Accounting Review, 43, October, 684-696.
Feltham, Gerald A. (1972): Information evaluation, Sarasota, FA: American Accounting Association.
Feltham, Gerald A. (1984): “Financial accounting research: Contributions of information economics and agency
theory”, in R. Mattessich, ed., Modern Accounting Research: History, Survey and Guide, Vancouver, BC:
Canadian Certified General Accountants Research Foundation.
Feltham, Gerald A. and Joel S. Demski (1970): “The use of models in information evaluation”, The Accounting
Review, 45, October, 623-640.
Feltham, Gerald A. and Jim Ohlson (1995): “Valuation and clean surplus accounting for operating and financial
activities”, Contemporary Accounting Research, 12, Spring, 689-731.
Feltham, Gerald A. and Jim Ohlson (1996): “Uncertainty resolution and the theory of depreciation measurement”,
Journal of Accounting Research, 34, 2, 209-234.
Financial Accounting Standards Board (1978): Objectives of financial reporting by business enterprises (Report
of the Study Group on Objectives: Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 1), Stamford, CT:
FASB.
Fisher, Irving (1906): The nature of capital and income , London: MacMillan & Co., Ltd.
Florentino, Américo M. (1965): Fundamentos matemáticos da contabilidade e suas aplicações na didática,
programação e análise contábil (Mathematical foundations of accounting and its educational application to
programming and bookkeeping analysis), Rio de Janeiro.
Fuerst, E. (1955): “The matrix as a tool in macro-accounting”, Review of Economics and Statistics 37, February.
Galassi, Giuseppe (1978): Sistemi contabili assiomatici e sistemi teorici deduttivi (Axiomatic accounting systems
and theoretical deductive systems), Bologna: Patron Editore.
García García, M. (1972): “Modernas tendencias metodológicas en contabilidad” (Modern methodological
accounting trends), Revista Española de Financiación y Contabilidad, I, 1, 23-44.
Gerhard, C. I., ed. (1962): G. W. Leibniz, Mathematische Schriften, Vol. VII: Meditatio juridico-mathematica de
interusurio simplice, Hildesheim (reprinted from the Halle edition of 1863), 125-132.
Givens, Horace G. (1966): “Basic accounting postulates”, The Accounting Review, 41, July, 458-463.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
145
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Gjesdal, F. (1981): “Accounting for stewardship”, Journal of Accounting Research, Spring, 208-231.
Goetz, Billy E. (1967): “Debit, credit and input-output tables”, The Accounting Review, 35, 3, July, 589-591 (in
Japanese in S. Koshimura, ed. translations of contributions by several authors from North America, Daisan
Shuppan, Ltd., 1969, 185-207).
Gordon, Myron J. (1960): “Scope and method of theory and research in the measurement of income and wealth”,
The Accounting Review, 35, October, 603-618.
Gutiérrez, J. M. (1990): “An axiomatic approach to inflation accounting”, IMA Journal of Mathematics Applied in
Business and Industry, 2, 197-207.
Gutiérrez, J. M. ( 1992): “On the gearing adjustment, an axiomatic approach”, Theory and Decision, 33, 207-221.
Gutiérrez, J. M. and G. Whittington (1997): “Some formal properties of capital maintenance and revaluation
systems in financial accounting”, The European Accounting Review, 6, 439-464.
Hansen, Palle (1962): The accounting concept of profit--An analysis and evaluation in the light of the economic
theory of income and capital, Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing.
Harada, Fujio (1978): Joho Kakei Ron (Accounting in a New Informational Society), Tokyo: Dobunkan, Ltd.
Heina, Fritz (1925): „Die Bewertung der Anlagen in Bergbaubilanzen einschließlich der steuerlichen Behandlung
der Substanzverringerung“ (Evaluation of fixed capital in the mining industry including the taxation of
insufficient capital maintenance), Zeitschrift für handelswissenschaftliche Forschung, 97-138.
Herde, Georg (1992): Präzisierung dreier axiomatischer Theorien des Rechnungswesens in einer formalen
Typentheorie (Making three axiomatic theories more précis), doctoral dissertation (published in bookform),
Bamberg, Otto-Friedrich-Universität.
Hess, Henry (1903): “Manufacturing: Capital, costs, profits, and dividends”, Engineering Magazine, 26, 367-379.
Hess, Henry (1910): “Manufacturing profits and losses”, Engineering Magazine, 39, 892-898.
Honko, Jaakko (1959): Yrityksen vuositulos (The annual income of an enterprise and its determination--A study
from the standpoint of accounting and economics), Helsinki: Oy Weilin & Göös Ab.
Ijiri, Yuji (1965a): Goal Oriented Models for Accounting and Control, Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co.
(originally doctoral dissertation, Carnegie Mellon University).
Ijiri, Yuji (1965b): “Axioms and structures of conventional accounting measurement”, The Accounting Review. 40,
January, 36-53.
Ijiri, Yuji (1967): The Foundations of Accounting Measures, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
Ijiri, Yuji (1971): “Axioms for historical cost valuation: A reply”, Journal of Accounting Research, 9, 1, 181-187.
Ijiri, Yuji (1975): Theory of accounting measurement, Sarasota, FA: American Accounting Association.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
146
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Ijiri, Yuji and Robert S. Kaplan (1971): “A model for integrating sampling objectives in auditing”, Journal of
Accounting Research, 9, 1, 73-87.
Jaedicke, Robert K. (1961): “Improving break-even analysis by linear programing“, N.A.A. Bulletin, Sect. 1,
March.
Jensen, Michael C. and William M. Meckling (1976):“ Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency cost, and
ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, October, 305-360.
Johnston, J. (1960): Statistical cost analysis, New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, Inc.
Käfer, K. (1962): Die Bilanz als Zukunftsrechnung-Eine Vorlesung über den Inhalt der Unternehmungsbilanz (The
future aspect of accounting--A lecture on the content of the entrepreneurial balance sheet), Zürich:
Universität Zürich.
Kempin, Walther (1910): Entwicklung der Bilanzlehre und der Abschlußtechnik (Development of accounting and
the closing technique), Cologne.
Knoeppel, C. E. (1920): Graphic production control , New York: Engineering Magazine Co.
Knoeppel, C. E. (1933): Profit engineering, New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc.
Koguchi, Yoshiaki (1990): “Towards a regional water management accounting system”, The Annual of the
Economic Research Institute of Chuo University, 21, Tokyo, 121-150.
Koshimura, Shinzaburo, ed. (1969): Contributions to matrix accounting (Japanese translation of three papers by
Mattessich [17-151], and one paper by each of the following authors: Allen B, Richards [153-173], Billy E.
Goetz [175-183], A. Wayne Corcoran [185-207]), Tokyo: Daisan Shuppan, Ltd.
Kosiol, Erich (1970): “Zur Axiomatik der Theorie der Pagatorischen Erfolgsrechnung“ (On the axiomatization of
the theory of cash flow earnings statement), Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft, 40, 135-162.
Kosiol, Erich (1978): Pagatoric theory of financial income determination, Urbana-Champaign, IL: University of
Illinois, Center for Education and Research in Accounting.
Lee, C. M. C. (1999): “Accounting-based valuation: impact on business practices and research”, Accounting
Horizons, 13, 4, 413-425.
Leibniz, Gottfried W. (see Gerhard, C. I., ed., 1962).
Leonardo de Pisa (see De Pisa, Leonardo).
Leontief, Wassily W. (1951): The Structure of the American Economy 1919-1939 , 2nd edition, New York, NY:
Oxford University Press (first edition, 1941).
Lev, Baruch (1969): Accounting and information theory, Evanston, IL: American Accounting Association.
Li, David H. (1968): Accounting, computers, management information systems, New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
147
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Lópes de Sá, Antonio (see Sá, Antonio, Lópes de).
Mann, John (Sir) (1903-07): “On cost or expenses”, in Encyclopedia of accounting, 8 vols., G. Lisle, ed.,
Edinburgh: William Green & Sons, Vol. 5, 199-225.
Marschak, Jacob (1974): Economic information, decision, and prediction —Selected essays, 3 volumes. D. Reidel
Publishing Company.
Marschak, Jacob, and K. Miyasawa (1968): “Economic comparability of information systems”, International
Economic Review, 9, 137-174.
Marschak, Jacob and Roy Radner (1972): Economic theory of teams, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Mattessich, Richard (1957): “Towards a general and axiomatic foundation of accountancy--With an introduction to
the matrix formulation of accounting systems”, Accounting Research 8, London, October, 328-355
(reprinted in Stephen A. Zeff, ed., The Accounting Postulates and Principles Controversy of the 1960s, New
York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc., 1982; Spanish translation in Técnica Economica, April 1958, 106-127;
Japanese translation in S. Koshimura, 1969, 17-79).
Mattessich, Richard (1961): “Budgeting models and system simulation”, The Accounting Review, 36, July, 384-397
(reprinted in T. H. Williams and C. H. Griffin, eds., Management information--A quantitative accent ,
Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 636-654.
Mattessich, Richard (1964a): Accounting and analytical methods--measurement and projection of income and
wealth in the micro- and macro-economy , Homewood, IL: R. D. Irwin, Inc. (reprinted in the "Accounting
Classics Series", Houston, Texas: Scholars Book Co., 1977; also in the "Series of Financial Classics" of
Reprints on Demand, Ann Arbor: Microfilms International, 1979, still available; German version under the
title: Die Wissenschaftlichen Grundlagen des Rechnungswesens, Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann
Universitätsverlag, 1970; Japanese translation under the direction of Shinzaburo Koshimura, Kaikei to
Bunsekiteki-Hoho Jokan , 2 vols., Tokyo: Dobunkan, Ltd., Vol. 1: 1972, Vol. 2: 1975; Spanish translation,
by Carlos Luis García Casella and Maria del Carmen Ramírez de Rodríguez, Buenos Aires: La Ley, 2002).
Mattessich, Richard (1964b): Simulation of the firm through a budget computer program (in collaboration with
Paul A. Zitlau and Thomas C. Schneider), Homewood, Illinois: R.D. Irwin, Inc. (reprinted in the Reprints
on Demand Series, still available on special order, Ann Arbor: Microfilms International, 1979).
Mattessich, Richard (1970): Die Wissenschaftlichen Grundlagen des Rechnungswesens (Abbreviated and revised
German version of Accounting and analytical methods), Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag.
Mattessich, Richard (1973): “On the axiomatic formulation of accounting: Comment on Professor S. Saito’s
considerations”, Sangyo Keiri, 33, March, in Japanese, 70-77 and April, 71-75. (English translation in The
Musashi University Journal, 21, 1/2, 1973, 77-94).
Mattessich, Richard (1995): Critique of accounting--Examination of the foundations and normative structure of
accounting, Westport, CT: Quorum Books, Greenwood Publishing Group, Inc.
Mattessich, Richard (1998): “From accounting to negative numbers: A signal contribution of Medieval India to
mathematics”, Accounting Historians Journal, 25, 2, 129-145.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
148
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Mattessich, Richard (2000): The beginnings of accounting and accounting thought --Accounting practice in the
Middle East (8000 B.C. to 2000 B.C. ) and accounting thought in India (300 B.C. and the Middle Ages), New
York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc.
Mattessich, Richard (2003): “Accounting research and researchers of the nineteenth century and the beginning of
the twentieth century: an international survey of authors, ideas and publications”, Accounting, Business and
Financial History, 13 , 2, July, 171-205.
Mattessich, Richard (2005): “The information economic perspective of accounting—its coming of age”,
Vancouver, BC: Accounting Working Paper, Sauder School of Business, University of British Columbia.
Mattessich, Richard and Giuseppe Galassi (2000): “History of the spreadsheet: from matrix accounting to budget
simulation and computerization”, in AECA ed., Accounting and History—Selected Papers from the 8th
Congress of Accounting Historians. Madrid: Asociación Española de Contabilidad y Administración: 203232 (Spanish translation as: Historia de la hoja de cálculo, in Revista Internacional Legis de Contabilidad &
Auditoria, 18, April-July, 2004: 41-86).
McGuire, C. B. (1972): “Comparison of information structures”, in C. B. McGuire R. Radner, eds., Decision and
organization, Amsterdam: North-Holland: 101-130.
McHaney, R. (2000): “Spreadsheets”, in R. Rojas, editor in chief, Encyclopedia of computers and computer history,
vol. II, M-Z, Chicago: Fitzroy Dearborn Publishers, 728-729.
McRae, T. W. (1964): The impact of computers on accounting, New York, NY: Wiley & Sons.
Miller, M. H. and F. Modigliani (1961): “Dividend policy, growth and the caluation of shares”, Journal of
Business, 34, 411-433.
Minor, Arthur J. (1933): “Mathematics behind the profit graph”, in Profit engineering, New York: McGraw-Hill,
Inc., Chpt. 15.
Mock, Theodore J. (1969): “Comparative values of information structures”, Journal of Accounting Research, 7,
Supplement, 124-159.
Mock, Theodore J. (1971): “Concepts of information value and accounting”, The Accounting Review, 46, October,
765-778.
Mock, Theodore J. (1976): Measurement and accounting information, Sarasota, FA: American Accounting
Association.
Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1958): “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment”,
American Economic Review, 48, 655-659.
Moonitz, Maurice (1961): The Basic Postulates of Accounting, New York, NY: American Institute of CPAs.
Moonitz, Maurice and Louis H. Jordan (1963): Accounting—An analysis of its problems, 2 vols., revised edition,
New York, NY: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc. (previous editions by M. Moonitz and C. C. Staehling
under the same title, 1950 and 1952).
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
149
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Murphy, G. J. (1996): “Mattessich, Richard V. (1922- )”, in M. Chatfield and R. Vangermeersch, eds., A History of
Accounting---An International Encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland Publishing Co. Inc., 404-406.
Noreen, Eric (1988): “The economics of ethics: A new perspective on agency theory”, Accounting, Organizations
and Society, 13, 4, 359-370.
Ohlson, James A. (1987a): The theory of financial markets and information , New York, NY: North-Holland.
Ohlson, James A. (1987b): “On the nature of income measurement: The basic results”, Contemporary Accounting
Research, Fall, 1-15.
Ohlson, James A. (1990): “A synthesis of security valuation theory and the role of dividends, cash flows, and
earnings”, Contemporary Accounting Research (Spring): 648-676 (reprinted in R. Mattessich, ed.,
Accounting Research in the 1980s and its Future Relevance , Vancouver, BC: The Canadian General
Accountants Research Foundation, 1991, 157-181.
Ohlson, James A. (1995): “Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation”, Contemporary Accounting
Research, 11, Spring, 661-687.
O’Leary, Daniel E. (1992): Expert systems in finance, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Onida, Pietro (1970): I moderni sviluppi della dottrina contabile nord americana e gli studi di economia aziendale,
Milano: Giuffrè (English version: “Modern developments of the North American accounting doctrine and
the studies of business economics”, in Accademia Nazionale di Ragioneria--Papers on Business
Administration, Vol. I, Milano: Giuffré, 1974, 149-222).
Orbach, Kenneth N. (1978): Accounting as a mathematical measurement theoretic Discipline, College Station, TX:
Texas A & E University, published, Ann Arbor, MI: University Microfilms.
Pacioli, Luca (1494): Summa di arithmetica, geometria, proportioni et proportionalita, Venice.
Parker, R. H. (1969): Management accounting: An historical perspective, London: MacMillan.
Paton, William A. (1922): Accounting theory--With special reference to the corporate enterprise, New York, NY:
Ronald Press (reprinted in the Accounting Classics Series, Lawrence, KA: Scholars Book Co.).
Peasnell, Kenneth V. (1982): “Formal connections between economic values and yields and accounting numbers”,
Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 9, August, 361-381.
Pichler, O. (1953): „Anwendung der Matrizenrechnung auf betriebswirtschaftliche Aufgaben“, Ingenieur Archiv,
21, 3, 119-140.
Prakash, P. and Alfred Rappaport (1977): “Information inductance and its significance for accounting”,
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 2, 1, 28-38.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1932): “Stock yields, stock dividends and inflation”, The Accounting Review, 7,
December, 273-289.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
150
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Preinreich, G. A. D. (1933): “Taxation and the natural business year”, The Accounting Review, 8, December, 317322.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1936a): “The fair value and yield of common stock”, The Accounting Review, 11,
March, 130-140.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1936b): “The law of goodwill”, The Accounting Review, 11, December, 317-329.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1937a): “Goodwill in accountancy”, Journal of Accountancy, January, 28-50.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1937b): “Valuation and amortization”, The Accounting Review , 12, June, 209-235.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1938): “Annual survey of economic theory: The theory of depreciation”, Econometrica,
6, January, 219-241.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1939): “Economic theories of goodwill”, Journal of Accountancy, July, 169-180.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (1941): “Note on the theory of depreciation”, Econometrica, January, 80-88.
Preinreich, Gabriel A. D. (edited by Richard B. Brief) (1996): A landmark in accounting theory: The work of
Gabriel A. D. Preinreich, New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc., 1996.
Rautenstrauch, Walter (1922): “The budget as a means of industrial control”, Chemical and Metallurgical
Engineering, 27, 415-416.
Rautenstrauch, Walter (1930): The successful control of profits, New York, NY: B.C. Forbes.
Requena Rodríguez, J. M. (1972): “Teoría de la contabilidad: Análisis dimensional” (Accounting theory: Multidimensional analysis), Revista Española de Financiación y Contabilidad, I, 1, 45-53.
Requena Rodríguez, J. M. (1977): La homogeneización de magnitudes en la ciencia de la contabilidad
(Homogenization of valuation in accounting theory), Madrid: Ediciones ICE.
Richards, Allen B. (1960): “Input-Output Accounting for Business”, The Accounting Review, 35, 3, July, 429-36
(reprinted in Thomas H. Griffin and Charles H. Griffin, 1967, 626-635; translated in S. Koshimura, 1969,
153-173).
Rieger, Wilhelm (1928): Einführung in die Privatwirtschaftslehre (Introduction to business economics), Nürnberg.
Rosenblatt, David (1957): “On linear models and the graphs of Minkowski-Leontief matrices”, Econometrica, 25,
325-328.
Rosenblatt, David (1960): “Aggregation in matrix models of resource flows II, Bolzano relation matrix methods”,
The American Statistician, 21, June, 32-37.
Rossi, Giovanni (1889): Lo scacchiere anglo-normanno e la scrittura in partita doppia a forma di scacchiera (The
Anglo-Norman exchequer and the double-entry chessboard), Roma: Botta.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
151
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Rossi, Giovanni (1901): Teòrica matemàtica della scrittura doppia (Mathematical theory of double -entry
bookkeeping), Genova.
Sá, Antonio, Lópes de (1995): “Axiomas em contabilidade científica” (Axioms in academic accounting).
Informativo Cientifico Cultural 1 (Setembro--Orgâo do Centro de Estudos Superiores de Contabilidade,
Belo Horizonte, Minas Gerais, Brazil), 1-5.
Saito, Shizuki (1972): “Considerations on the axiomatic formulation of accounting”, (originally in Japanese) in
Kaikei , 101, 1972, 45-65; English translation in The Mushashi University Journal, 20, 81-99).
Saito, Shizuki (1973): “Further considerations on the axiomatic formulation of accounting: A reply to Prof. R.
Mattessich”, The Mushashi University Journal, 21, 95-107.
Savage, L. J. (1954): The foundations of statistics, New York, NY: Wiley & Sons.
Schneider, Dieter (1973): “Renaissance der Bilanztheorie?“ (Renaissance of accounting theory?), Zeitschrift für
betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung 25 (1): 29-58.
Schneider, Dieter (1981): Geschichte betriebswirtschaftlicher Theorie (History of the theory of business
economics), München: Oldenbourg Verlag, 1981, 3rd. ed. 1987. This book has now been completely
revised and is being published in four volumes under the title Betriebswirtschaftslehre, Vol. 1: Grundlagen,
1993; Vol. 2: Rechnungswesen, 1994; Vol. 3: Theorie der Unternehmung, and Vol. 4: Geschichte und
Methoden—for the latter see separate entry).
Schweitzer, Marcel (1970): „Axiomatik des Rechnungswesens“ (Axiomatic of accounting), in Erich Kosiol, ed.,
Handwörterbuch des Rechnungswesens, Stuttgart: Poeschel Verlag, 83-90.
Schweitzer, Marcel (1972): Struktur und Funktion der Bilanz (Sructure and function of the balance sheet), Berlin:
Duncker & Humblot.
Seicht, Gerhard (1970): Die kapitaltheoretische Bilanz und die Entwicklung der Bilanztheorie (The capital-theoretic
balance sheet and the development of accounting theory), Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.
Shank, John K. (1972): Matrix methods in accounting, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Slaymaker, Adrianne E. (1996): “Conceptual framework”, in Michael Chatfield and Richard Vangermeersch, eds.,
The History of Accounting: An International Encyclopedia,. New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc.: 150154.
Smith, Eugen, C. (1974): Application of the techniques of matrix algebra to determine consolidated net income in
complex affiliations (doctoral dissertation—no further data available).
Sprouse, Robert T. and Maurice Moonitz (1962): A tentative set of broad accounting principles for business
enterprises, New York, NY: American Institute of Certified Public Accountants.
Stevin, Simon (1582): Tafeln van interest (Interest tables), Antwerp.
Stigler, J.G. (1961): “The economics of information”, Journal of Political Economy , 69, 213-25.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
152
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Stigler, J.G. (1962): “Information in the labor market”, Journal of Political Economy , 70, 5, Part 2, Supplement,
94-105.
Stringer, K. W. (1961): “Some basic concepts of statistical sampling in auditing”, Journal of Accountancy,
November, 63-69.
Study Group of the University of Illinois (1964): A statement of basic accounting postulates and principles,
Urbana, IL: Center for International Education and Research in Accounting.
Sweeney, Henry W. (1937): “Accounting postulates: An analysis of the tentative statement of Accounting
principles: Comments”, The Accounting Review, 12, October, 404-406.
Thierauf, Robert J. (1990): Expert systems in finance and accounting, New York, NY: Quorum Books.
Trenchant (Jan) Jean (1558): L’Arithémique departie en troys livres, Lyons.
Trueblood, Robert M. and R. M. Cyert (1954): “Statistical sampling applied to aging of accounts receivable”,
Journal of Accountancy, 97, March, 293-298.
Trueblood, Robert M. and William W. Cooper (1955): “Research and Practice in Statistical Applications to
Accounting, Auditing, and Management Control”, The Accounting Review, 30, 221-229.
Tucker, James J. (1996): “Statistical sampling”, in M. Chatfield and R. Vangermeersch, eds., The history of
accounting: An international encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc., 557-561.
Vance, Lawrence L. (1950): Scientific methods for auditing, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Vance, Lawrence L. and John Neter (1956): Statistical sampling for auditors and accountants, New York, NY:
John Wiley and Sons, Inc.
Volmer, Frans (1996): “Stevin, Simon (1548-1620)”, in M. Chatfield and R. Vangermeersch, eds., The history of
accounting: An international encyclopedia, New York, NY: Garland Publishing, Inc., 565-566.
Wagenhofer, Alfred (2004): “Accounting and economics: What we learn from analytical models in financial
accounting and reporting”, in C. Leutz, D. Pfaff, and A, Hopwood, eds., The economics and politics of
accounting. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 5-31.
Wagenhofer, A. and R. Ewert (2003): Externe Unternehmensrechnung (Financial accounting), Berlin: Springer
Verlag.
Wells, Murray C. (1971): “Axioms for historical cost valuation”, Journal of Accounting Research, 9, 171-180.
Wells, Murray C. (1976): “A Revolution in accounting thought”, The Accounting Review, 51, July, 471-482.
Wenke, Klaus (1956): “Kostenanalyse mit Matrizen“, Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft, 26, October, 558-576.
Wenke, Klaus (1959): “On the analysis of structural properties of large scale micro-economic input output models“,
Reprints of the International Meeting of the Institute of Management Sciences , London: Pergamon Press.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
153
Richard Mattessich: A concise history of analytical accounting: examining
the use of mathematical notions in our discipline
_______________________________________________________________________________
Willett, Roger J. (1985): Accounting measurement theory, Weatherby, WY: Ph.D.-Dissertation, University of
Aberdeen--British Library Documentation Supply Centre.
Willett, Roger J. (1987): “An axiomatic theory of accounting measurement” (Part I), Accounting and Business
Research, 17, Spring, 155-172.
Willett, Roger J. (1988): “An axiomatic theory of accountin g measurement” (Part II), Accounting and Business
Research, 19, Winter, 79-91.
Williams, John H. (1922): “A technique for chief executives”, Bulletin of the Taylor Society, 51.
Williams, Thomas H. and Charles H. Griffin, eds. (1964): The Mathematical Dimension of Accounting,
Cincinnati, OH: South-Western.
Williams, Thomas H. and Charles H. Griffin, eds. (1967): Management information--A quantitative accent ,
Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.
Williamson, D. E., M. L. Wachter, and J. E. Harris (1975): “Understanding the employment relation: The
analysis of idiosyncratic exchange”, The Bell Journal of Economics, Spring, 119-132.
Winborne, Marilynn G. (1962): Application of sets and symbolic logic to selected accounting principles and
Practices, Austin, TX: Ann Arbor, MI: Doctoral dissertation, University of Michigan.
Zappa, Gino (1920-29): La determinazione del reddito nelle imprese commerciali--I valori di conto in relazione
alla formazione dei bilanci (Profit Determination of Business Enterprises--Bewertung in Financial
Statements), Rome: Anonima Editoriale Italiana.
Zappa, Gino (1937): Il reddito di impresa--Scritture doppie, conti e bilanci di aziende commerciali, 2nd edition (The
enterprise income—double entry, accounts and balance sheets of commercial firms), Milan: A. Giuffrè (3rd
printing of 2nd edition 1950).
Zeff, Stephen A., ed. (1982): The accounting postulates and principles controversy of the 1960s, New York, NY:
Garland Publishing, Inc.
_________________________
Richard Mattesich es Profesor emérito en la Saider School of Business, Faculty of Commerce and Business, de la
University of British Columbia, Vancouver, B.C. V6T 1Z2, Canadá, donde desempeña una Cátedra distinguida de
Contabilidad. Es uno de los más renombrados epistemólogos de contabilidad del mundo.
Richard Mattessich is Professor Emeritus at the Sauder School of Business, Faculty of Commerce and Business
Administration, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, B.C. V6T 1Z2, Canada, where he held a distinguished
Chair of Accounting. He is one of the world most renowned specialists on accounting epistemology.
______________________________________________________________________________
DE COMPUTIS
Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad
Spanish Journal of Accounting History
No. 2
Junio 2005
Descargar