Subido por canizales1985

presentation rr webinar 281123 final

Anuncio
Are Markets Asleep at the Wheel?
Riccardo Rebonato
Scientific Director, EDHEC-Risk Climate Impact Institute
Professor of Finance, EDHEC Business School
1
Outline of Presentation
1. Plan of the Session
2. Statement of the Problem
3. Do Prices Respond to Climate Shocks?
4. Are Climate Outcomes Price-Relevant?
➢ Does Unmanaged Climate Risk Matter for Asset Prices?
➢ Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
5. An Optimistic Estimate
6. A Bit of Theory
7. Conclusions
2
Plan of the Session
▶ A large number of studies have failed to date to identify a robust
and economically significant climate risk premium or climate beta,
either at the aggregate or at the sectoral level.
▶ How can this be the case?
▶ I intend to argue that a mispricing of climate risk is the most likely
explanation.
▶ If this is true, price adjustments will eventually occur, either in a
gradual or in an abrupt way.
▶ This is a novel source of risk, which should be on the radar screen
of long-term investors.
3
Statement of the Problem
In a recent review paper Acharya (2023) argues that
▶ “[w]hile [the] literature has convincingly documented that climate
risks are currently priced across a range of asset classes, much less is
known about whether they are adequately priced. [This] is,
however, an important question for assessing the likelihood of
potentially substantial short-run asset revaluations as there
might be strong [...] revisions in the price of risk associated with the
inherently evolving nature of climate risk realizations. [...]
▶ If investors fail to [...] update beliefs in response to information
about future climate risk realizations, this might reduce the average
present-day effects of long-run physical climate risks [...];
... , it could also lead to more substantial revaluation risk in case
beliefs eventually move by a substantial amount”.
4
Statement of the Problem
Why do we think that markets could be ‘asleep at the wheel’?
▶ First, attempts to detect a ‘climate beta’ (the sensitivity of different
asset classes to climate shocks) have so far been met with mixed
success at best: there is no universal agreement as to which asset
classes have a positive or a negative climate beta, and the price
sensitivity has always been found to be at the limit of detectability
(of statistical significance).
▶ Economic significance is even more dubious than statistical
significance.
▶ This suggests that, if prices have so far reflected climate information,
they must have done so to a very limited extent.
5
Statement of the Problem
▶ Second, this muted sensitivity of prices to climate news is difficult
to reconcile with the expected economic outcome of any climate
policy:
1.
2.
if we deal with climate change seriously, the transformation of the
whole economy will have to be radical (with adaptation and
abatement costs of the same order of magnitude as what we
currently spend on education or defence);
if the climate change problem is left untackled, temperatures on
the planet are likely to reach levels never experienced by the
human species – with potentially serious economic consequences.
▶ This is why the muted sensitivity of asset prices to climate
innovations constitutes a puzzle.
6
Statement of the Problem
What could the explanations be? These are the most likely possibilities:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
the market is informationally efficient and has already impounded
all the relevant information;
the market is informationally efficient, but it expects the climaterelated cashflow impairment to be small for all sectors, even if no
significant climate action is taken;
the market is informationally efficient, but it is confident that the
climate-related cashflow impairment to be small because it
believes that climate risk will be effectively managed – eg, the
temperatures will remain within the Paris Agreement 1.5-2 C
target;
the market is informationally efficient, believes that climate
damages will be significant, but these damages occur so far in the
future that they are effectively ‘discounted away’.
the market is ‘asleep at the wheel’, by which we mean that the
prices do not correctly reflect expectations and uncertainty about
climate outcomes.
7
Do Investors Believe in Climate Change?
Figure 1: Breakdown of political affiliations for beliefs about climate change.
Figure 2: Breakdown of political affiliations for beliefs about climate change.
8
Do Investors Believe in Climate Change?
Figure 3: “The effects of climate finance are everywhere apart from in the prices”.
9
Statement of the Problem
We think that price adjustments are likely because...
▶ If the market erroneously underestimates the reality/gravity of
climate change, and as corporate cashflows over time turn from
‘discounted expected’ to ‘realized’, and expectations will have to
change.
▶ Revision in expectations that will then give rise to large
price-adjustments.
▶ If, instead, the market is pricing in a ‘soft landing’ scenario:
1. this outcome should not be taken as an almost certain scenario (big
uncertainty);
2. it would have very strong sectoral effects (which instead appear
small); and.
3. it is extremely optimistic, since the 1.5 C target is in practice
virtually unachievable, and that even 2 C is a ‘stretch’.
10
Do Prices Respond to Climate Shocks?
▶ The most direct way to estimate a climate beta is to carry out a
regression of observed asset returns against a suitable climate index
(after controlling for the other known factors).
▶ Unfortunately, there is no obvious observable proxy for climate risk.
▶ Different approaches have therefore been followed to create an
index (a time series) representative of climate risk, eg, from textual
analysis.
▶ The out-of-sample explanatory power of these early indices has been
low: after controlling for established factors, the incremental R²
statistics is of the order of a few percentage points.
▶ Using an advanced version of this approach, Maeso and O’Kane
(2023) obtain statistically more significant result, but, then again,
only for one special combination of the several indices they build.
11
Do Prices Respond to Climate Shocks?
▶ Given these problems, Chini and Rubin (2022) have tried to capture
latent factors and time-varying loadings by introducing observable
characteristics that instrument for the unobservable dynamic
loadings.
▶ When they use this technique to explain the returns of corporate
bonds, they find that a ‘[s]ystemic environmental factor does not
help to explain bond returns on top of financial standard factors’.
▶ In the case of equities, only for the most obvious sectors, Oil and
Utilities, the increase in the R² is statistically significant, and even
in this case by very modest amounts (a few percentage points).
12
Do Prices Respond to Climate Shocks?
▶ A separate strand of research (see, eg, the work by Pastor and
Staumbaugh (2022)) has looked at the construction of long-short
portfolios, whose returns should be proportional to the latent
climate factor.
▶ This approach has one significant advantage over the index route:
perhaps there has been a readjustment of prices, but this has
occurred as a gradual process of growing climate awareness, not
directly linked to specific ‘climate news’.
▶ There is a problem, though: it is not obvious which securities should
go in the long and short portfolios (indeed, the approach is
somewhat circular).
13
Do Prices Respond to Climate Shocks?
▶ Whatever the sorting method, the results are far from clear, with
the field evenly but unhelpfully split:
▶ half the researcher find that only the returns of green assets are
affected by climate risk;
▶ the other half draw the same conclusion but for brown assets.
▶ As Chini and Rubin (2023) conclude, “[b]y choosing different
measures [one obtains] different results: [the] sign of the ‘greenium’
[and hence of the climate beta] is not clear.”
14
Are Climate Outcomes Price-Relevant?
▶ We said that a possible explanation of why prices appear to respond
so little to climate information could be either
1. because climate damages are expected to be small even if climate
risk is left unmanaged; or
2. because the market expects that efficient mitigation actions
(emission abatement, carbon removal, adaptation) will limit
climate change or make its effects ‘innocuous’.
▶ The distinction matters:
1. If ‘climate change does not matter’, then no big readjustments of
the economy will be required.
2. But if it is mitigation and adaptation that will mute the effect of
climate change, this will require a major re-wiring of the whole
economy, and sectoral effects should be strong.
▶ We therefore look at these two possibilities separately.
15
Does Unmanaged Climate Risk Matter for
Asset Prices?
▶ The first possibility (that unmanaged climate risk will have little
effect on cashflows) is difficult to justify.
▶ Under a business-as-usual scenario, the concentration of CO2 in the
atmosphere would most likely continue to grow at its current rate,
which, it should be remembered, is still almost exponential, as shown in
Exhibit 3.
▶ Exhibit 4 shows the modest decrease in the exponential growth rate
experienced since the 1960s.
16
Does Unmanaged Climate Risk Matter for Asset Prices?
Figure 4: The natural logarithm of the CO2 annual emissions from 1900 and a linear fit.
Figure 5: same quantity for the years 1960 to date and a quadratic fit.
17
Does Unmanaged Climate Risk Matter for
Asset Prices?
▶ If emissions continue along the current business-as-usual trajectory,
temperature increases around 3 C and possibly more by the end of
the century are very likely¹.
▶ The associated economic damages are admittedly very imperfectly
know.
▶ However, a number of serious studies project very severe
consequences.
▶ Even if there is disagreement about the magnitude of the economic
damages, the sheer magnitude of the uncertainty about what could
happen should be reflected in prices.
¹ The human species has never experienced these temperatures, as we have to go back some three million
years ago to find similar global temperatures
18
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Could it be that the market correctly expects the effect of climate
change to be successfully managed?
▶ This is very optimistic because
1. we are very uncertain also about temperature outcomes given CO2
concentrations – therefore a strong confidence in our ability to
engineer a ‘soft climate landing’ is misplaced;
2. the policy changes required for the soft landing are
unprecedented, both quantitatively and qualitatively;
3. these policy changes are difficult to reconcile with the possible
development trajectories of those parts of the world (such as subSaharan Africa) that have not experienced sustained economic
growth to date.
▶ Let’s consider these points in turn.
19
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Could it be that the market correctly expects the effect of climate change
to be successfully managed?
▶ The sharpness of the target of 1.5 to 2 C of warming by 2100
suggests that we can steer our emissions to achieve a desired
temperature with tenth-of-degree precision.
▶ Indeed, this is the impression conveyed by graphs such as those
shown in Exhibit 5.
▶ The reality is very different.
▶ One of the key inputs to the climate models used to link emissions
to temperature is the Equilibrium Climate Sensitivity.
▶ Exhibit 7 shows a fit to the dispersion of estimates of this quantity
found in the literature for this key variable.
20
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 6: Emission paths consistent with 1.5 C warming by 2100.
Figure 7: Emission paths consistent with 2.0 C warming by 2100
21
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 8: Emission paths consistent with 1.5 C warming by 2100.
22
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 9: Historical and projected emission path consistent with 2 C warming by 2100.
Figure 10: Temperature outcomes consistent with the same emission path for different climate models.
23
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
▶ Clearly, the inversion of the historical emission trend required to
stay, on average, below 2 C must be sudden and extremely steep.
▶ If not at a global level, has a similar rate of decline been observed at
least for some countries?
▶ What were the policy choices of these fast abaters?
▶ Could, in short, the experience of these countries become a
template for successful decarbonization?
24
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
▶ One must distinguish carefully between
1. developed countries;
2. fast developing countries;
3. countries that still have to develop
▶ The development trajectory of the still-to-develop countries holds
the key to future global warming.
▶ Part of the reason is that early stages of development rely heavily
on sectors (steel, cement) that are very difficult to decarbonize.
25
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 11: Emissions (India).
Figure 12: Emissions (China).
26
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 13: Emissions (US).
Figure 14: Emissions (France).
27
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 15: Emissions (Nigeria) – cement ≊ 10%.
Figure 16: Emissions (Kenya) – cement > 10%.
28
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Summarizing our results so far:
▶ If we focus on cement-related emissions as a proxy for emissions
that are difficult to curb via renewables, we distinguish three clear
different patterns:
1. for strongly developing countries such as China and India, they are
growing roughly at the same pace as total emissions;
2. for developed countries, they are in general falling faster than total
emissions are;
3. for still-to-develop countries they are growing at a faster pace than
their total emissions.
▶ See Exhibit 17.
29
Will Climate Risk Be Successfully Mitigated?
Figure 17: The fraction of the cement-related emissions to total emissions against the GDP/person
(x axis, average of the 2015-2020 data) for 20 countries. Best fit to the function frac = α × GDPβ
Figure 18: Ratio cement-to-total CO2 emissions for several countries.
30
An Optimistic Estimate
▶ Let us be optimistic and assume that the rate of emission reduction
similar to what has been achieved by the best-in-class.
▶ If replicated on a global scale, would the cuts in the emissions
carried out by the most ‘aggressive’ countries be enough to meet
the 2 C target?
▶ If everybody started cutting emissions tomorrow at the fastest
sustained pace so far observed anywhere in the world, would the
global abatement curve be as steep as the right part of the graph in
Exhibit 8?
31
An Optimistic Estimate
Figure 19: Per capita CO2 emissions (France).
Figure 20: Share of energy consumption by source (France).
32
An Optimistic Estimate
If we consider that
1.
2.
3.
the fast pace of emission reduction experienced by the fastest
abater (France) was due to a nuclear choice that currently few
countries seem willing to embrace;
that even if the French rate of emission reduction were somehow
universally adopted, we would in all likelihood still fall short of the
2 C target;
that many highly emitting countries are still increasing their carbon
emissions,
it seems very unlikely that the pace of abatement will be as high as
required by a trajectory such as the one shown in Exhibit 8.
33
An Optimistic Estimate
A soft-landing scenario therefore implicitly relies
1.
on all countries adopting abatement policies faster than what has
been observed for the fastest abaters to date – achieved thanks to
a unique commitment to nuclear energy – and faster than the
current pledges;
2.
on technological breakthroughs occurring very soon in carbon
sequestration and storage, in direct carbon removal, and in largescale non-fossil-fuel solutions for the production of cement, steel
and nitrates;
3.
on these breakthroughs being shared (presumably with
accompanying subsidies) with developing economies.
4.
This is not a central scenario.
34
A Bit of Theory
▶ To arrive at prices, cashflows must be discounted. What is the
correct discount rate?
▶ Consider the simplest case (no uncertainty, time-separable CRRA
utility functions) of the Ramsey equation, which derives the
discount rate, r , as
r=δ+γg
where δ is the rate of impatience (the utility discount rate), γ is the
inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, and g is the
rate of consumption growth (Δ log c) – closely linked to the rate of
growth of the economy.
▶ Ramsey’s equation assume certain cashflows – a very dubious
assumption.
35
A Bit of Theory
▶ If we allow for uncertainty, we get
where σ²(Δ log c) denotes the variance of consumption growth.
▶ If anything, the presence of additional uncertainty due to climate
risk would increase the variance of consumption, and the
precautionary-savings term would make the discount rate lower.
36
A Bit of Theory
▶ If there is such a large degree of uncertainty about the correct
discount rate, are firm conclusions about its effects unwarranted?
▶ Weitzman shows that in the case of uncertainty about the correct
discount rate, for distant cashflows one should use the lowest
possible rate – the more distant the cashflow, the lower the rate of
discounting.
▶ And, with a not-particularly low discounting rate of 2%, cashflows
in 40 years’ time do not disappear – they are reduced by 55%.
▶ Therefore, even if climate damages were a very long way in the
future, they would still produce a change in discount rate.
▶ Barring near-miraculous cancellations, this change in discounting
should have affected today’s prices.
37
Conclusions
▶ A black-and-white description of the current global-warming
predicament points to two polar scenarios:
1. if we control effectively climate change, the world economy will have to
undergo a transformation that some macroeconomists have described as
‘precipitous’;
2. or we venture into uncharted climate waters, with temperatures fast
approaching and perhaps exceeding levels (3 C) never experienced by the
species Homo Sapiens.
▶ There are, of course, shades of grey, but not much room for maneuver: just
one more decade of ‘muddling through’ would effectively close most realistic
pathways to 2 C by 2100.
▶ Plus, there is much greater uncertainty about the physics of the problem
than we usually acknowledge.
▶ Even the more benign scenarios hide, behind the facade of a smooth
aggregate transition, profound macroeconomic shifts, which must
have deep sectoral price reverberations.
38
Conclusions
▶ In either of the polar scenarios above, and in all the intermediate
outcomes, transition and physical climate risk will have large
aggregate and/or differential impacts on cashflows of firms and
governments.
▶ If, as we have suggested, these have not been properly factored in
current valuations, significant price adjustments can be expected.
If these price adjustments will be gradual, this will create a
long-term drag on portfolio returns. This would be the most benign
form of repricing.
▶ There are precedents, however, of much more sudden price
adjustments – look no further than the 2008-2009 subprime crisis...
▶ Volatility and loss of liquidity can also be expected, with potential
macrostability implications.
39
Slow Response of Equity Markets...?
Figure 21: The Nasdaq index 2006-2009.
Figure 22: The Non-Investment OAS spread 2006-2009.
Figure 23: Base correlation 2006-2009
40
Conclusions
Can one guess the timing of the readjustment (of the ‘Minsky
moment’)?
▶ Every real-world or financial crisis (COVID, Russia/Ukraine,
disruption to energy supply, inflation shocks) temporarily pushes
climate abatement off the attention radar, and delays the transition
(desire for ‘energy security’ versus ‘acceleration renewables’).
▶ The more ‘crises’ we experience, the larger the final readjustment is
likely to be.
▶ In the West and in the Global South, opposition to climate change
is rising among ‘populists’, who are depicting climate-change
concerns as ‘rich, white people’s worries’.
41
Conclusions
Can one guess the timing of the readjustment (of the ‘Minsky
moment’)? – ctd.
▶ The high level of public and corporate debt makes investment in
abatement policies more difficult – also in this respect, every crisis
(military support for Ukraine, COVID furlough schemes, fiscal help
for the energy crisis) reduces the available resources for abatement.
▶ Government intervention is more needed for the second phase of
decarbonization: removal, capture and storage. Fiscal room (UK
‘Truss episode’) and willingness to raise taxes (US) are limited.
▶ All of this can only delay the enactment of effective policies.
▶ Every policy delay makes the climate damages higher, and the
potential final price readjustments more abrupt.
42
Conclusions
What could trigger the repricing?
▶ Extremely difficult to tell.
▶ If sudden, the Minsky moment could be due to an exceptional
weather event, perhaps localized in a major Western urban centre,
with high media coverage.
▶ An unexpected and sweeping regulatory move could have a catalytic
effect as well – the two could be linked.
▶ For the high-impact regulatory move to have ‘legitimacy’ and to be
politically possible, it would probably have to come in the wake of
some high-profile instance of physical damage, again probably in a
Western country.
43
Q&A session
44
Thank you!
About us:
Marking the priority assigned by the School to sustainability issues and building on its
research programmes exploring the relationships between climate change and finance,
EDHEC-Risk Institute became EDHEC-Risk Climate Impact Institute (EDHEC-Risk Climate) in
the Fall of 2022. EDHEC-Risk Climate’s mission is to help private and public decision-makers
manage climate-related financial risks and make the best use of the financial tools
available to transition to low-emission and climate-resilient economies. Our core ambition
is to become a leading academic reference point for long-term investors, helping them to
manage the asset-pricing implications of climate change. We also aim to play a noted role
assisting financial supervisors and policy makers assess climate-related risks in the financial
system and advising on policy and tools to mitigate those risks, and optimise the
contribution of finance to climate change mitigation and adaptation
Contact us:
For general enquiries about this research, please contact:
[email protected]
For press or media-related enquiries, please contact:
[email protected]
45
Disclaimer:
The present deck of slides is academic work is an academic paper published for general scientific
purposes and is not, and should not be construed as, investment advice or other advice, nor is it
intended to be relied upon in making an investment or other decision. Neither EDHEC Business School
nor the authors are responsible for the content of the information resources referenced in the
publication, and reference to a source does not constitute an endorsement. Unless expressly stated
otherwise, a reference to an organisation, trade name, trademark, product, or service does not
constitute or imply an endorsement, sponsorship, or recommendation. Unless expressly stated
otherwise, the opinions, recommendations, findings, interpretations, and conclusions appearing in this
report are those of the authors and do not represent an official position of the EDHEC-Risk Climate
Impact Institute, EDHEC Business School, or any research sponsor. While we have endeavoured to
ensure that the information appearing in this report is up to date and reliable, we make no
representation or warranty of any kind, expressed or implied, about its timeliness, completeness,
accuracy, reliability, or suitability for any purpose. Neither EDHEC Business School nor any research
sponsor is responsible for any error or omission in this report or for any decision made or action taken
based on the information contained therein. In no event shall EDHEC Business School, the authors, or
any research sponsor be liable for any loss or damage arising from or caused by such decision or
action.
46
Descargar