0895- 7177J93 $6.00 + 0.00 Mafhl. Comput. Modelling Vol. 17, No. 415, pp. 13-18, 1993 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPON Copyright@ 1993 Pergamon Press Ltd zyxwvutsrqpon Printed in Great Britain. All rights reserved EXPERIMENTS REVERSAL ON RANK PRESERVATION AND IN RELATIVE MEASUREMENT THOMAS L. SAATY Joseph M. Katz Graduate School of Business, 322 Mervis Hall University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, PA 15260, U.S.A. Lurs G. VARGAS Joseph M. Katz Graduate School of Business, 314 Mervis Hall University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, PA 15260, U.S.A. Abstract-We show through simulation that three methods of scaling, distributive (uniqueness is important), ideal (uniqueness is not important), and utility (use of interval scales for the ideal) modes, yield the same ranking of alternatives with surprisinglyhigh frequency, except for the case of copies or near copies of an alternative in which the distributive mode always reverses rank, which is legitimate when the uniqueness of the most preferred alternative is important. 1. INTRODUCTION It has been assumed rather than deduced by practitioners of Multi-attribute Utility Theory (MAUT) that when ranking alternatives to either choose one or several and allocate resources to them, or use them as scenarios in forecasting, the addition or deletion of a new alternative should never cause a change in the existing ranking. This belief is predicated on the assumption that a new alternative can only cause change in the old rankings if it introduces a new criterion or if there is a change in the weights of the old criteria. However, an increasing number of counterexamples [l] have appeared in the literature which demonstrate that rank reversals do occur in practice in a way that does not satisfy these assumptions. For example, there are times when the presence of a copy or near copy of a best alternative diminishes its importance by depriving it of uniqueness as, for example, in shopping for a hat or a tie. On seeing too many copies of an attractive alternative one abandons it for a less attractive one that is unique. There are decisions where uniqueness is not an important criterion as, for example, buying a computer or a car of which there are many copies. In utility theory alternatives are rated one at a time on a set of standards defined by a utility function. Adding a new alternative does not affect the rating of other alternatives. Because uniqueness depends on how many alternatives there are, and one of the assumptions of the utility approach is that criteria should be independent of the alternatives, uniqueness cannot be addressed by this approach. However, uniqueness can be addressed through relative messurement, an alternative approach to absolute measurement in the AHP when either there are no standards to establish intensities or acceptable utilities for criteria or the standards are inapplicable. It follows that to make a decision one may need to know something about the alternatives to determine whether uniqueness should be considered. The AHP [2-4] has four modes for scaling weights to rank alternatives. The first is the absolute mode [5] which assumes prior knowledge of standards. In this mode, alternatives are rated one at a time and there can be no reversal in the old ranks when new alternatives are added. The second is the distributive mode [2] involving normalization of the weights derived from paired comparisons of the alternatives. It allows one to rank alternatives with the possibility of rank reversal when uniqueness is important as in buying a painting, a hat, and other collectible items, and when it is desired to allocate limited resources. The third is the ideal mode [l,S] and it involves dividing by the weight of the highest ranked alternative for each criterion. This mode is used when it is desired to choose a best alternative without regard to uniqueness, such as in buying a car or a computer. Both methods, the distributive mode and the ideal mode, produce a Typeset by A,# - ‘Y&X 13 14 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA T.L. SAATY, L.G. VARGAS ranking on a ratio scale. However, in the former, the final weights of the alternatives depend on each other both before and after synthesis through weighting and adding. In the latter, adding a new alternative necessitates that it be compared with the highest ranked alternatives for each criterion. Traditionally, it has been held that it is reasonable to expect a dominating alternative on some criterion to cause rank reversal. Unless the new alternative dominates the highest ranked one for some criterion, it cannot affect the ranks of the existing alternatives. When in the ideal mode the ratio scale measurements of the alternatives are transformed to interval scales it is known as the utility mode. Some utility theorists believe that under appropriate interpretation, such a transformation would not even cause a dominating alternative to effect change in the ranks of the old alternatives-but the counterexamples have clearly shown that such a condition is too stringent to be satisfied in practice. The fourth mode, known as the supermatrix approach [3, p. 1991, allows one to consider dependencies between different levels of a feedback network, of which a decision hierarchy is a particular case. We thought to do a large number of random experiments on a three level hierarchy of criteria and alternatives to see how often rank reversals occur. Our findings very strongly support the observation that the ideal mode should be used to choose the best alternative when the presence of copies and near copies or perturbations of copies do not matter. But when it does one should use the distributive mode. None of our experiments give any evidence favoring a shift to interval scales. Table 1. Number of times that the most preferred alternative remains most preferred. DISTRIBUTIVE No. of Criteria IDEAL MODE MODE No.of Zriteria Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 992 2 961 957 964 969 973 979 979 979 2 971 965 977 987 985 992 990 3 958 951 955 959 958 970 971 973 3 953 967 973 976 985 987 992 995 4 946 933 931 933 959 965 952 964 4 960 949 957 964 981 977 989 988 5 924 926 940 934 955 941 944 961 5 947 952 964 967 977 981 984 988 6 951 957 955 974 979 973 979 985 6 929 922 928 941 942 943 959 962 7 921 938 927 917 924 958 953 957 7 936 947 955 968 953 974 974 983 8 926 920 931 934 945 949 957 943 8 945 942 953 957 971 985 979 987 9 915 916 926 927 933 936 945 948 9 939 929 963 966 964 985 977 980 UTILITY N o. of Criteria MODE zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONM Number of Alternatives I 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 910 935 954 963 981 987 977 988 881 907 936 945 963 976 981 989 866 907 925 943 956 964 973 971 851 901 919 939 953 950 965 966 856 878 901 923 940 959 957 961 860 901 903 919 935 963 961 971 870 877 897 925 924 957 955 971 867 872 920 917 939 948 944 964 2. EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN AND RESULTS In this note, we experimentally study the impact that the addition of a new alternative in a hierarchy has on the final ranking of the alternatives. We have assumed without loss of generality that the hierarchies have three levels: the goal, criteria, and alternatives. The number of criteria and the number of alternatives vary from 2 to 9. Thus, the total number of different hierarchies in our experiment is equal to 64. 15 zyxwvutsrqpo Ftank preservation Table 2. Itank preservation of the hrst and second most preferred alternatives. DISTRIBUTIVE No. of %iteria IDEAL MODE MODE N o. of Criteria Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 964 967 953 965 973 981 984 980 985 921 956 942 949 962 966 962 St% 987 913 957 934 933 935 960 956 966 971 914 SO4 948 913 939 936 944 951 966 968 895 887 896 941 918 908 923 945 958 962 960 871 867 906 878 926 901 910 933 949 940 949 963 872 841 882 896 933 903 924 916 939 940 950 957 867 928 896 898 906 913 932 949 957 882 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGF 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 959 935 933 936 936 955 929 939 910 899 901 SO8 905 SO3 944 893 874 878 889 900 915 938 858 879 862 873 869 921 876 863 866 869 910 862 847 852 925 868 849 817 919 844 841 852 828 Number of Alternatives 874 9 UTILITY MODE Number of Alternatives N o. of Criteria 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 877 887 904 949 961 955 960 971 852 827 873 888 915 933 937 964 877 808 843 869 912 914 932 939 873 778 830 855 885 SO6 923 931 858 810 831 839 878 903 913 917 851 808 812 863 881 885 917 920 850 788 797 854 863 881 910 929 832 770 807 829 841 887 902 908 Table 3. Rank preservation of all alteratives. DISTRIBUTIVE No. of Xteria IDEAL MODE MODE No. of Number of Alternatives Number of Alternatives zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFED Criteria 7 8 9 6 7 8 9 2 3 4 5 6 4 5 2 3 963 935 896 866 844 828 802 763 2 967 959 944 948 941 949 938 949 941 873 862 838 766 725 706 687 3 951 932 922 926 906 914 913 925 708 665 614 4 955 915 893 888 890 886 908 881 939 882 843 798 728 922 880 827 765 699 675 623 593 5 942 910 902 889 892 870 869 874 928 848 801 756 683 641 630 574 6 955 896 883 871 859 874 866 850 932 847 800 744 691 652 603 552 7 953 916 880 862 866 853 842 842 940 841 792 743 672 650 567 523 8 951 904 870 872 846 857 832 845 908 854 794 728 655 609 548 526 9 937 SO3 866 836 831 827 838 832 UTILITY MODE No. of Criteria Number of Alternatives I zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXW 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 903 887 896 874 883 884 868 903 854 805 814 833 811 827 816 815 880 815 801 788 796 800 792 789 873 812 764 750 760 769 734 768 842 815 756 771 720 721 739 751 857 804 748 718 720 730 711 726 860 791 757 718 713 716 689 701 858 798 722 704 695 702 692 664 16 T.L. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA SAATY, zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONML L.G. VARGAS Table 4. Rank preservation of the most preferred alternative. DISTRIBUTIVE MODE vs. IDEAL MODE BEFORE AN ALTERNATIVE No. of Cri t&a DISTRIBUTIVE No. of Zriteria Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 5 6 7 MODE vs. IDEAL MODE AFTER AN ALTERNATIVE IS ADDED 8 9 IS ADDED Number of Alternatives zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGF 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 2 983 973 954 936 942 961 957 950 2 970 966 953 940 957 958 954 954 3 974 942 932 929 922 942 929 924 3 944 936 934 929 921 937 928 925 4 960 946 918 923 919 929 927 913 4 925 924 909 912 932 922 920 920 5 967 935 929 898 907 908 897 919 5 939 928 913 904 901 899 891 912 6 955 946 915 889 903 910 891 905 6 924 904 900 895 890 907 895 905 7 956 921 915 882 883 881 878 898 7 922 902 904 888 888 890 878 901 8 947 912 899 877 883 890 871 881 8 917 897 906 892 896 885 872 883 9 970 941 896 882 887 885 883 891 9 911 911 888 880 892 886 871 896 DISTRIBUTIVE MODE vs. UTILITY BEFORE AN ALTERNATIVE MODE DISTRIBUTIVE IS ADDED No. of Criteria Number of Alternatives N o. of Criteria 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 MODE vs. UTlLITY AFTER AN ALTERNATIVE 9 MODE IS ADDED zyxwvutsrqponmlk Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 934 2 842 893 898 890 914 927 937 930 2 878 902 894 906 930 929 938 3 854 824 854 857 874 898 890 889 3 861 859 866 873 874 906 897 896 4 819 812 846 833 855 881 884 872 4 790 821 829 847 872 858 884 892 877 5 808 822 837 820 847 845 856 877 5 805 838 834 842 845 844 857 6 810 793 818 798 837 847 845 852 6 803 796 834 811 819 869 857 866 7 810 795 821 798 809 840 821 852 7 783 801 820 813 826 838 834 856 8 785 793 808 803 820 831 814 827 8 784 791 826 831 829 830 828 834 9 820 818 793 801 813 824 824 826 9 780 804 810 806 834 836 824 851 IDEAL MODE vs. UTILITY BEFORE AN ALTERNATIVE No. of Zriteria MODE IDEAL IS ADDED Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 MODE AFTER 6 7 8 9 MODE IS ADDED Number of Alternatives N o. of 5 vs. UTILITY AN ALTERNATIVE /Criteria 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 2 859 919 937 944 960 961 971 975 2 901 932 937 949 967 967 976 973 3 872 874 917 907 929 942 951 944 3 903 912 920 926 942 954 958 950 4 853 865 903 894 916 924 939 945 4 855 887 908 914 928 915 949 950 5 837 870 893 888 916 923 932 942 5 858 892 904 912 928 924 946 945 6 845 838 881 888 916 923 932 942 6 865 870 909 897 913 952 930 929 7 836 853 877 887 893 928 912 931 7 848 874 893 906 912 931 930 926 8 832 860 875 894 910 926 916 918 8 841 867 899 917 908 918 936 928 9 844 861 864 885 901 919 924 914 9 856 873 889 905 904 919 932 930 For each hierarchy, we generated, at random, goal, and the weights of the alternatives were uniform transformed mode. (0,l) Let cj, j= with respect alternatives variates. according The weights to three methods: 1,2 ,..., to criterion with respect the weights of the criteria with respect to each criterion. of the alternatives the distributive m be the weights of the criteria, with respect mode, with respect These random to the weights to the criteria the ideal mode, were and the utility let wij be the weight of alternative j, and let ~J~zI wij = 1. For the distributive mode, zyxwvutsrqp i the weight of the to the goal is given by: m Wi Z zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHG c j=l Wij Cj . Flank preservation 17 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIH Table 5. Rank preservation of the two most preferred alternatives. DISTRIBUTIVE BEFORE N o. of (hiteria MODE vs. IDEAL AN ALTERNATIVE Number 2 3 4 DISTRIBUTIVE MODE AFTER IS ADDED No. of Zriteria of Alternatives 5 6 7 8 MODE vs. IDEAL AN ALTERNATIVE MODE IS ADDED Number of Alternatives 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 9 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCB 938 899 883 882 874 867 905 885 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA 2 880 2 982 927 892 881 882 878 901 3 969 904 882 836 841 822 839 827 3 893 889 855 829 841 820 836 829 4 959 890 840 815 805 798 779 776 4 882 846 810 767 796 796 801 785 5 959 892 841 781 766 756 760 762 5 863 828 794 789 777 768 753 756 6 968 866 832 798 754 742 741 739 6 865 820 790 770 762 757 735 736 7 951 849 814 781 747 762 746 755 7 862 807 785 763 752 743 736 735 8 954 861 794 762 761 734 723 749 8 878 816 764 755 752 727 736 732 9 966 844 787 774 733 736 745 726 9 852 807 750 758 731 708 734 724 DISTRIBUTIVE BEFORE MODE vs. UTILITY AN ALTERNATIVE No. of Zriteria Number 2 3 DISTRIBUTIVE MODE AFTER IS ADDED of Alternatives MODE 5 6 7 8 9 MODE IS ADDED Number of Alternatives No. of Criteria 4 vs. UTILITY AN ALTERNATIVE 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 848 2 867 789 770 796 805 813 844 833 2 788 815 774 809 806 814 853 3 833 727 695 718 719 744 762 771 3 709 717 710 727 742 749 775 770 4 814 782 675 667 696 681 699 698 4 693 680 683 656 693 687 733 699 5 808 648 653 652 648 649 632 686 5 672 643 656 670 666 654 654 680 6 807 671 656 635 640 623 639 648 6 661 629 627 626 636 629 627 660 7 829 647 641 615 606 613 656 661 7 614 616 617 620 632 638 665 8 789 669 594 608 627 615 618 658 8 643 611 585 628 639 631 628 642 9 813 645 602 633 593 600 631 646 9 650 614 601 634 613 596 630 647 IDEAL BEFORE MODE vs. UTILITY MODE AN ALTERNATIVE IDEAL AFTER IS ADDED MODE vs. UTILITY AN ALTERNATIVE Number Number of Alternatives of Alternatives 5 6 7 8 9 2 3 4 5 844 876 889 881 920 914 835 879 866 782 821 816 869 875 889 793 802 810 773 779 775 828 819 862 850 783 767 835 721 748 794 800 795 806 832 754 827 747 753 779 808 784 823 827 864 746 753 749 747 768 821 819 743 714 736 775 791 837 741 737 772 765 785 2 3 4 885 850 858 792 849 For the ideal mode, MODE IS ADDED 6 7 8 9 895 893 904 923 934 824 851 872 891 890 807 796 830 846 872 856 751 785 818 824 815 836 841 743 735 773 773 804 800 828 034 827 743 740 757 773 759 780 821 849 799 815 706 721 740 769 796 803 818 831 883 815 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJ 717 739 738 788 782 793 833 837 we have: viE jt; (m$ywjj~ > 5. And for the utility mode we have: zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDC Wij Ui - lllinj 3 {Wij} Cj. Kltij {Wij} - zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJ Iklj {Wij} > A new alternative was then introduced and assigned a random weight also from a uniform (0,l) variable for each criterion. This random variate was then added to the set of random variates T.L. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA SAATY. L.G. VARCAS 18 under each criterion and the three transformations mentioned above were applied to obtain the new weights of the alternatives with respect to the goal. The old ranking of the alternatives is now compared with the new ranking. We performed three distinct sets of simulations (sample size of 1000). First, we estimated the frequency with which the distributive, the ideal, and the utility methods preserve the rank of the most preferred alternative when a new alternative is added (see Table 1). Second, we estimated the frequency with which the ranking of the two most preferred alternatives is preserved after the addition of a new alternative (see Table 2); and third, we estimated the frequency of any rank reversal when a new alternative is added to the set (see Table 3). In addition, we compared the three methods in pairs. In Table 4 we give the results of estimating the frequency with which the distributive, the ideal, and the utility methods yield the same most preferred alternative before and after a new alternative is added. In Table 5 we give the results of comparing the methods in pairs, but estimated the frequency with which two methods yield the same two most preferred alternatives before and after a new alternative is introduced. We also simulated the addition of copies and near copies (10 percent deviation on either side of a weight). 3. CONCLUSIONS The results of the simulation show that all three methods yield the same answer with surprisingly high frequency, except for the addition of copies or near copies for which the distributive mode always reversed rank as expected. Our conclusion is that to choose a zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZY best alternative if a new alternative is added to the set of alternatives and the alternative is a copy or a near copy of an existing one, then one should use the distributive mode if the uniqueness of the choice is important; otherwise, one should use the ideal mode. In case of resource allocation and interdependent scenarios to predict the future, the distributive mode is needed because all the alternatives play a role in the final outcome. REFERENCES 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. T.L. Saaty, Resolution of the rank preservation-reversal issue, Working Paper, University of Pittsburgh, (1992). T.L. Saaty, Scaling method for priorities in hierarchical structures, Journal of Math. Psych. 15, 234-281 (1977). T.L. Saaty, zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA M ulticriteria Decision Making: The Analytic Hierarchy Process, Original version published by McGraw-Hill, 1980, RWS Pub., Pittsburgh, (1990). T.L. Saaty, Axiomatic foundation of the analytic hierarchy process, Management Science 32, 841-855 (1986). T.L. Saaty, Rank generation, preservation and reversal in the analytic hierarchy decision process, Decision Sciencea 18, 157-177 (1987). E.H. Forman, Rank adjustment and rank reversal-And how to evaluate thousands of alternatives with AHP, Working Paper, George Washington University, (1992).