Subido por Javier Callis

Hurrell -Hegemony liberalism and global order

Anuncio
Hegemony, Liberalism and Global Order: What Space for Would-Be Great Powers?
Author(s): Andrew Hurrell
Source: International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-), Vol. 82, No.
1, Perspectives on Emerging Would-Be Great Powers (Jan., 2006), pp. 1-19
Published by: Oxford University Press on behalf of the Royal Institute of International
Affairs
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3569127
Accessed: 16-07-2018 00:24 UTC
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/3569127?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Royal archive
Institute
of International
Affairs,
University
areavailable
collaborating
with
Your use of the JSTOR
indicates
your acceptance
of theOxford
Terms &
Conditions Press
of Use,
at
JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to International Affairs (Royal Institute of
http://about.jstor.org/terms
International Affairs 1944-)
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order:
what space for would-be great powers?
ANDREW HURRELL*
In an international system dominated by the United States it is hardly surprising
that the actual and potential behaviour of important second-tier states should
be a source of recurring interest. This article, and the four that follow, consider
some of the ways in which China, Russia, India and Brazil have responded
both to US hegemony and to the changing character of international society.
In this article I set out some of the major analytical questions that emerge when
thinking about the foreign policy options of these countries and some of the
principal conceptual and theoretical categories within which those questions
may be usefully framed. The first section examines the reasons for taking these
countries as a group. The second section provides a brief overview of two of
the most common theoretical perspectives from which the systemic pressures
on these countries have been understood. The third, and longest, section considers actual and potential strategies and options under five headings: regional
preponderance and major power status; international institutions and institu-
tional enmeshment; relations with the United States; the possible emergence of
balancing behaviour; and, finally, the links between economic development
and foreign policy. The focus is on foreign policy options and understandings
of those options, rather than on an assessment of the power resources of these
countries or of their economic trajectories.
China, Russia, India, Brazil: common factors and distinguishing features
Why look at these particular countries? One reason is that they all seem to possess
a range of economic, military and political power resources; some capacity to
contribute to the production of international order, regionally or globally; and
some degree of internal cohesion and capacity for effective state action. Particularly in the cases of China and India, increased attention has followed from
* This introduction and the articles on Russia, China and India that follow were originally presented at a
conference on 'Hegemony, order and emerging powers' at the University of Brasilia in April 2005. I
would like to thank those present for their comments and the Centre for Brazilian Studies and the Centre
for International Studies in Oxford, as well as the University of Brasilia, for their support of this project.
International Affairs 82, I (2006) I-I9
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
their high levels of economic growth and from projections of their future
economic development and its possible (although usually underspecified) geopolitical and geo-economic implications.' Picking up an old line of commentary, analysts in the late I99os also identified Brazil as a 'pivotal state' or one of
the 'Big Ten' emerging markets, 'countries like China, India, and Brazilwhich are acquiring enough power to change the face of global politics and
economics'.2 Russia is the outlier: as MacFarlane argues in his article in this
issue, the reality of the past two decades here has been one of decline and the
dissolution of power. Nevertheless, its foreign policy is focused on trying to
arrest that decline and seeking to reassert regional and global influence.
A second reason is that all of these countries share a belief in their entitle-
ment to a more influential role in world affairs. Aspiration alone, of course, is
not enough, and it is easy for the hard-headed realist to scoff at the empty
pretensions of those states whose ambitions run ahead of their material capabilities. And yet power in international relations requires a purpose and project,
and the cultivation of such a purpose can both galvanize national support and
cohesion at home and serve as a power resource in its own right. Think of Nehru
or De Gaulle. Moreover, the search for recognition in which these four countries are united is a fundamental part of the politics of hierarchy. Challenges to
the legitimacy of international order have rarely resulted from the protests of
the weak; they have come more often from those states or peoples with the
capacity and political organization to demand a revision of the established order
and of its dominant norms in ways that reflect their own interests, concerns and
values. Thus a central theme of twentieth-century international history was the
struggle of revisionist states for Gleichberechtigung-equal rights-involving the
redistribution of territory, the recognition of regional spheres of influence, and
the drive for equality of status within formal and informal international
institutions. However much the currency of power or the rules of the power-
political game may have changed, this pattern of behaviour remains an
important element of global politics. Although the likelihood of military
confrontation between major powers may have been lessened, the issue of
recognition has been sharpened by the growth of the idea that international
society should aim to promote shared values and purposes rather than simply
underpin coexistence and help to keep conflict to a minimum.
A third reason for considering these four countries together flows from the
development of relations between and among them. The articles that follow
make reference to many such developments: Chinese and Russian cooperation
through the Shanghai Cooperation Organization (SCO); joint Sino-Russian
Dominic Wilson and Roopa Purushothaman, Dreaming with the BRICs: the path to 2050, Global
Economics Paper no. 99 (New York: Goldman Sachs, Oct. 2003). See also Arvind Virmani, Economic
performance, power potential and global governance: towards a new international order, working paper no. i50
(New Delhi: Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations, Dec. 2004).
2 Jeffrey E. Garten, The Big Ten: the big emerging markets and how they will change our lives (New York: Basic
Books, I997), p. xxv; Robert Chase, Emily Hill and Paul Kennedy, eds, The pivotal states: a new
frameworkfor US policy in the developing world (New York: Norton, I999), esp. pp. I65-94.
2
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
military exercises; rapprochement between China and India; the emergence of
the G20 within the WTO as a new southern coalition lead by Brazil and India;
the strengthening of ties between India and Brazil (and South Africa) in the
form of IBSA; the expansion of Chinese economic relations with India and
Brazil. Such developments are picked up with alacrity by those looking for
signs of a coordinated willingness to challenge Washington, or for evidence of
emerging multipolarity and a renewed potential for systemic revisionism.
The final reason is that these four countries can be differentiated from other
second-tier states and middle-sized powers. John Ikenberry has argued powerfully that one of the most important characteristics of the international system
in the second half of the twentieth century was the emergence of a US-led
order built around the institutional and multilateral structures created in the
wake of the Second World War (the UN, GATT, the international financial
institutions) and the extraordinarily dense set of transatlantic and trans-Pacific
relations and alliance systems.3 This mostly liberal 'Greater West' represented
novel political formation which, although strained by the post-Cold War
emergence of the US as the sole superpower and threatened by recent US
policies, continues to be a very important feature of the system. But what is
important here is the degree to which Brazil, Russia, India and China all lie
either outside, or on the margins of, this formation. Unlike Japan, South
Korea, Canada, Australia and the major European countries (as a bloc and
individually), they are not closely integrated in an alliance system with the
United States.4 More broadly, they have all historically espoused conceptions
of international order that challenged those of the liberal developed Westfrom the (at least rhetorical) revolutionism of the Soviet Union and China to
the hard-revisionist Third Worldism of post-1948 India and the soft-revisionist
Third Worldism of Brazil from the early 1970s to the late I98os.
Since the Cold War all four of these countries have been faced not simply by
the extent of US power but also by dramatic changes in the character of
international society-the exponential increase in the number of international
institutions and in the scope, range and intrusiveness of international rules and
norms; the increased pluralism of global governance, with the growing role of
NGOs, networks of technical specialists, and private and hybrid public-private
forms of regulation and ordering; the consolidation of the idea that international
society should go beyond simple coexistence and should instead embody and
reflect a range of internationally agreed core principles such as those relating to
human rights and democracy, self-determination, constraints on the use of
3 G. John Ikenberry, 'Liberalism and empire: logics of order in the American unipolar age', Review of
International Studies 30: 4, Oct. 2004, pp. 609-30; and After victory: institutions, strategic restraint and the
rebuilding of order after major war (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 200I).
4 Brazil's membership of the OAS and Rio Pact makes it a partial exception. However, as we shall see,
for most of the period since I945 its relationship with Washington has not been particularly close. It is
also an exception in cultural and historical terms, although its foreign policy has long been characterized
by a tension between those espousing terceiro-mundismo ('Third Worldism') and those favouring closer
integration with the industrialized world.
3
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
force, and environmental sustainability; and, finally, increased demands that
more effective 'teeth' be given to the norms of international society, involving
both collective enforcement action by the United Nations and increased
delegation to international tribunals, as well as a wide and expanding range of
multilateral sanctions and conditionalities.
These moves from a traditional pluralist view of international society to one
characterized by greater solidarism have undoubtedly represented a substantial
challenge to countries such as Brazil, Russia, India and China. They challenged
the strong, albeit varying, preference of these states for the older pluralist norms
of sovereignty and non-intervention.5 They interacted in problematic ways with
the complex processes of economic and political liberalization taking place in
all of these states-and, more importantly, with the limits and contested
character of that liberalization. And they challenged traditional modes of
conducting foreign policy, privileging new kinds of soft power and rewarding
new kinds of diplomacy. This is a further point of differentiation from liberal
modernist middle powers such as Canada or Australia, whose foreign policies
have been built around the promotion and exploitation of these very changes.
Finally, the changing norms of international society have had a significant
impact on the character of the great power club. Being a great power has never
been solely about the possession of large amounts of crude material power. It
has been closely related to notions of legitimacy and authority. A state can
claim great power status, but membership of the club of great powers is a social
category that depends on recognition by others: by your peers in the club, but
also by smaller and weaker states willing to accept the legitimacy and authority
of those at the top of the international hierarchy. One of the difficulties facing
potential aspirants to the great power club is that the criteria for membership
may militate against them-as Japan found in I918-I9 over the issue of racial
discrimination. Or the criteria may change in ways that work against their
particular interests. For example, for much of the Cold War the possession of
nuclear weapons was widely seen as a necessary qualification for a seat at the
top table; but in the years since its end, acquisition of a nuclear weapons
capability has come to be seen as a sign of unacceptable behaviour and potential
status as a rogue state. If, as Foot argues in her article in this issue, China is
intent on being seen as a 'responsible great power', how those understandings
of 'responsibility' have shifted is very much to the point.
There are, of course, substantial differences among these countries-in
terms of their power and geopolitical importance; in terms of their economic
weight and degree of integration into the global economy; in terms of their
s Although it is common to read off attitudes to international order from domestic characteristics (the
degree of political liberalization or the extent of economic reform), we should not discount the 'large
country syndrome'. Brazil, Russia, India and China have shared a preference for hard conceptions of
national sovereignty and, although sometimes professing a liking for multilateralism, have tended to
resist the effective delegation of authority to international bodies. In this, of course, they have much in
common with the United States. Within this company the European preference for more elaborate
forms of institutionalized global governance represents the outlier.
4
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
distinctive cultural and historical trajectories; and in terms of their domestic
political systems. Yet considering them together provides one useful way of
opening up a series of questions about the pathways to power that have been,
or might be, available to them, and about the explanatory factors that might
shed light on these varied pathways.
Theoretical perspectives
There are two theoretical narratives that constantly recur in discussions of how
the international system influences the foreign policies of Brazil, Russia, China
and India.
The first focuses on the distribution of power and on the patterns of power
politics that 'inevitably' result. For neo-realists, the crucial feature of any system
is the distribution of material power, and hence the dominant political reality
of the post-Cold War order is the preponderance of the United States. Military
power and war are central to understanding how power is distributed and what
counts as a great power: 'Great powers are determined on the basis of their
relative military capability. To qualify as a great power, a state must have suffi-
cient military assets to put up a serious fight in an all-out conventional war
against the most powerful state in the world.'6 From this perspective, the
puzzle of the post-Cold War period, and even more of the post-September I I
period, has been the absence of overt balancing behaviour against the United
States. Some explain this simply as a reflection of the overwhelming power of
the United States.7 Others suggest that whether or not balancing behaviour
occurs reflects not just the fact of US power but rather how the US uses that
power. US predominance will be stable to the extent that Washington plays to
its soft power strengths and its reputation for non-expansionist intentions.8
Thus the US will get more of what it wants if it recognizes the extent and
potential of its soft power and acts judiciously on that recognition. Yet others
argue that stability depends on the idea of self-restraint and on US willingness
to engage with international institutions as a means of signalling that strategic
restraint. A rational hegemon will engage in a degree of self-restraint and institutional self-binding in order to undercut others' perceptions of threat.9
The most important implications of this mode of analysis are, first, that it
sees the concentration of power itself as an important determinant of foreign
policy and, second, that it casts the foreign policy options available to second6 John J. Mearsheimer, The tragedy of great power politics (New York: Norton, 2001), p. . For a historical
survey of the idea that 'the self-revelation of a great power is completed by war', see Martin Wight,
Power politics (Harmondsworth: Penguin/RIIA, I979), ch. 3.
7 William C. Wohlforth, 'The stability of a unipolar world', International Security 24: I, I999, pp. 5-4I.
8 Joseph S. Nye, Soft power: the means to success in world politics (New York: Public Affairs, 2004). As Joffe
notes, one of the advantages of soft power is that it complicates the notion of counterbalancing: 'Against
soft power, aggregation does not work. How does one contain the power that flows not from coercion
but from seduction?'. See JosefJoffe, 'Gulliver unbound: can America rule the world?', the John
Bonython Lecture, Sydney, 5 Aug. 2003.
9 G. J. Ikenberry, 'American grand strategy in the age of terror', Survival 43: 4, Winter 2001/2, pp. 19-34.
5
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
tier states in binary terms: balancing against the dominant state on the one
hand, or bandwagoning with it on the other. Although there are significant
differences between the defensive and offensive versions of neo-realism, both
consider that the emergence of new powers will naturally tend to create
power-political tensions.
Neo-realist theory has generated an enormous and sophisticated literature
with many subtheories and competing diagnoses. It is, however, limited in a
number of important ways. In the first place, most of this literature is written
from the perspective of the United States and is implicitly or explicitly
preoccupied with the strategies that the US has adopted, or should adopt, to
sustain its advantageous position in the system. Second, the foreign policy
choices of second-tier states are arrived at deductively, irrespective of whether
or not they correspond particularly closely either to policy options that have
actually been adopted or to understandings of those choices within second-tier
states themselves. Third, the options are underspecified: What precisely does
'bandwagoning' consist of, and what determines the choice among the very
different forms that 'alignment' with the hegemon might take? Does bandwagoning describe a pattern of behaviour or a conscious policy choice? Is it
useful to distinguish between hard and soft forms of balancing? What of other
options such as 'hiding' or 'hedging'? Finally, neo-realism sees the system only
in terms of the distribution of power. Systemic forces are indeed crucial; but, as
foreign policy analysis of the countries under consideration here clearly
demonstrates, there is much more in the system than is contained in neo-realist
theory, and this matters not just for accurate empirical analysis but also for the
development of successful theory.
A second cluster of theoretical approaches highlights not the continuity of
conflict and power-political competition but rather powerful changes under
way in both international and global society, especially those associated with
globalization. The central claim is that new kinds of systemic logic have gathered
a force that will enmesh and entrap even the most powerful. A new raison de
systeme is developing that will alter and ultimately displace old-fashioned
notions of raison d'etat. Since the end of the Cold War liberal versions of these
well-established arguments have dominated the field.
For institutionalist liberals, globalization and ever denser networks of trans-
national exchange and communication create increasing demand for international institutions and new forms of governance. Institutions are needed to
deal with the ever more complex dilemmas of collective action that emerge in
a globalized world. As large states expand their range of interests and integrate
more fully into the global economy and world society, they will be naturally
drawn by the functional benefits institutions offer and pressed towards more
cooperative patterns of behaviour. Institutions are important in helping to
explain how new norms emerge and are diffused across the international
system, and how state interests change and evolve. Institutions may play an
important role in the diffusion of norms and in the patterns of socialization and
6
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
internalization by which weaker actors come to absorb those norms. Institutions may be the locations where state officials are exposed to new norms (as on
the environment); they may act as channels or conduits through which norms
are transmitted (as neo-liberal economic ideas have been through the IFIs); or
they may reinforce domestic changes that have already begun to take place (by
means of either state strategies of external 'lock-in' or pressures exerted
through transnational civil society).
Systemic liberals build on many of the same core ideas but develop a broader
Kantian image of the gradual but progressive diffusion of liberal values, as a
result partly of liberal economics and increased economic interdependence,
partly of a liberal legal order coming to sustain the autonomy of a global civil
society, and partly of the successful example set by the multifaceted liberal
capitalist system of states. Some lay particular emphasis on the intrinsic
rationality of economic liberalization: statist economic models having clearly
failed, rational behaviour on the part of Brazil, Russia, India and China will
produce a growing foreign policy convergence to maximize the opportunities
presented by economic globalization. Others suggest that there was little
option but to accept the intrinsic superiority of the ideas that have conquered
the world. Others stress the role of the third wave of democratization, sweeping away authoritarian nationalist governments and the statist-nationalist
coalitions that had often supported them. And still others stress the role of
transnational movements, advocacy networks and epistemic communities in
reshaping understandings of state interest.
For the proponents of this view, these developments serve to shift the
currency of power, in particular devaluing hard, military power. They also alter
the dynamics and effects of aggregations of power. Instead of being seen as
threatening and prompting balancing responses, concentrations of liberal power
will create a liberal version of bandwagoning. Just as the example of a liberal
and successful EU has created powerful incentives towards emulation and a
desire for membership, so, on a larger scale and over a longer period, a similar
pattern will be observed in the case of the liberal, developed world as a whole.
In any case, to resist the liberal order is to risk being categorized together with
rogue regimes and with the enemies of economic and political freedom.
Finally, the role of power will depend on which version of liberalism holds
sway in the core states, especially the United States: defensive liberals, who
believe that history is on their side and that, as Kant argued, it is the power of
example that is most critical and that will ultimately prove decisive; or offensive
liberals, who believe that history needs a helping hand and that processes of
economic and political liberalization should be actively promoted through the
exercise of state power, including the use of military force.'?
IO On this distinction see Benjamin Miller, 'The rise of offensive liberalism and the war in Iraq', paper
delivered at International Studies Association, Montreal, March 2004. The influence of offensive
liberalism is likely to reinforce the view, visible in all four of these countries, that the ideologies and
practices of economic globalization and of liberal solidarism are intimately connected to the hegemonic
power of the US and its closest allies.
7
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
These systemic arguments have implications for the analysis of Brazil,
Russia, India and China. First, they imply that these countries will come under
increasing pressure to adapt, and that the theoretical logic of this adaptation can
be best captured either by notions of rational adaptation, learning and technical
knowledge, or by notions of emulation, normative persuasion, socialization
and internalization. Second, they imply that the sources of resistance to change
are likely to be found within these societies in 'blocking' coalitions, made up of
the interest groups that grew powerful under previous economic and political
models, or in the continued power of older ideas and ideologies, often
embedded within state institutions.
Strategies and options
Regional preponderance and global power
There is something intuitively logical about the idea that regional preponderance should represent an important element of any claim to major power
status. A state may promote itself, or may be seen by others, as the representa-
tive of a particular region that in turn might be defined geographically,
linguistically, or in cultural or civilizational terms. This (contested) notion of
representativeness has been an important element in the debates over Brazilian
and Indian permanent membership of the Security Council. A state may see
the region as a means of aggregating power and fostering a regional coalition in
support of its external negotiations (as with Brazil and Mercosur in the face of
the Free Trade Area of the Americas). A state may seek to play an active and
assertive role in regional crisis management both to underpin its own claim to
regional power and also to ensure that it cannot be excluded from forms of
crisis management that are undertaken by outside players (as with China and
North Korea). Finally, a state may be seen as a major power to the extent that it
fulfils a managerial or order-producing role within its region. This, in turn,
may become an important element in its own relationship with international
institutions or with the United States.
And yet the cases of Brazil, Russia, India and China all bring out the complexity of the regional-global nexus. In all four cases foreign policy is heavily
shaped by the regional context-by evolving regional balances of power
(especially within South Asia and East Asia); by changing patterns of regional
insecurity (especially in the form of new categories of threat); and by increasingly dense patterns of social and economic regionalization. Regions are also
central to historic self-understandings. Both Russia and India see themselves as
the natural leader of a closed region in which outside interference is deeply
resented. And yet, on balance, it is the image of the region as constraint rather
than as opportunity that emerges most strongly from the four articles that follow.
In the first place, the region can be a source of weakness either because of
unresolved regional conflicts (for example, Taiwan or Kashmir) or because of
regional instability and the sheer difficulty of maintaining influence, as is most
8
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
obviously the case with Russia. The need to maintain regional power and to
prevent its further erosion has been a central feature of Russian foreign policy.
And yet the difficulties and costs of doing so have been, and remain, extremely
high. Its defeat in Chechnya in I994-5 and its subsequent failure to secure
stable control provide the clearest illustration of what MacFarlane sees as 'the
increasing incapacity of Russia's armed forces to maintain internal sovereignty'.
In addition, the methods that Moscow has used to maintain or recover its
influence have led to tensions in other important international alignments,
most notably in the case of Europe. Lima and Hirst note how Brazil under th
Lula administration has expanded the range of its political interests in South
America and has been prepared to assume a more assertive political role; but in
relation to the Andean region, it is becoming entangled in a crisis-prone area
without clearly being in possession of the economic or military resources t
play such a role. In the case of India, regional/global power balances and
sources of insecurity have interacted in particularly problematic ways.
The contrast with the United States is instructive. Much is made of the
unique position of the United States and the degree to which, unlike all
modem great powers, it faced no geopolitical challenge from within its r
and was able to prevent, or more accurately contain, the influence of ex
regional powers. This is certainly true (even if the rise of the US to reg
hegemony is often dated too early and its extent exaggerated). But the o
important regional aspect of US power is the ability to avoid excessively
entanglement or involvement and, for the most part, to escape from ensn
and diverting lower-level conflicts within its 'backyard'. It has been able to ta
the region for granted and, for long periods, to avoid having a regional p
at all (as has arguably been the case since 200I). It is this fact that, per
counterintuitively, provides Brazil with some capacity to develop a relat
autonomous regional role.
Second, attempts to develop a global role can easily stir the animosity,
least raise the concerns, of regional neighbours. This has been particularl
dent in the reactions of regional second-tier states to the attempt by Ind
Brazil to obtain permanent seats on the UN Security Council, and to Br
more assertive regional policy within South America more generally, espe
on the part of Argentina.
Third, the dominant power in the system may take the opportunity to exp
regional conflicts to its own advantage and to engage in offshore balanc
precisely the way in which neo-realist theory would predict. A similar, bu
often noted, logic applies to regional arrangements: the United States maximi
its power by promoting forms of regionalism so loosely institutionalized
they do not tie down or constrain the US but, at the same time, work to
undercut or forestall the emergence of other, smaller regional groupings that
could emerge as effective challengers to the US. This pattern has been visible in
the cases of both the Asia-Pacific region and the Americas.
9
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
International institutions and institutional enmeshment
Whatever their undoubted role as facilitators of common interest and promoters of shared values, institutions are sites of power, and unequal power has
played a consistently important role in both their construction and their opera-
tion. Thus, for example, the Cold War 'order' and the long peace of 1945-89
were constructed in very traditional fashion around attempts to regulate the
balance of power between the superpowers (through arms control agreements,
summits and mechanisms of crisis management) and through the exploitation
of hierarchy (through the mutual, if tacit, recognition of spheres of influence
and through the creation of an oligarchical non-proliferation system designed
to limit access by emerging powers to the nuclear club). Moreover, even as the
idea of sovereign equality gained ground and as international institutions
expanded so dramatically in both number and scope, hierarchy and inequality
remained central to both their conception and their functioning. Sometimes
the 'ordering' role of hierarchy was formalized, as in the special rights and
duties of the permanent members of the UN Security Council, or the
weighted voting structures of the IMF or World Bank. More often it can be
seen in powerful political norms, as in the practice of ad hoc groupings and
contact groups to deal with particular security crises, or the role of the G8 in
attempts to manage not just global economic issues but a great deal more
besides; or the way in which international financial management is dominated
by closed groups of the powerful (as in the Bank for International Settlements
or the Financial Stability Forum).
Against this background it is no surprise that aspiring major powers should
devote so much attention to playing the game of institutionalized hierarchy.
Hence we see Russia's preoccupation with the Security Council and its
keenness to participate in G8 summits. Hence what Foot calls the Chinese
'fixation' with the UN, and its resistance to any reform of the UN Security
Council that would add new permanent members. As Lima and Hirst indicate,
Brazil's campaign for a permanent seat on the Council has played a central role
in the country's determination to expand relations with the South more
generally, as well as on individual policies (as with its leading role in the UN
mission in Haiti or its voting pattern on human rights).
It is also unsurprising that, for Brazil and India, nuclear non-proliferation
should have been such an important issue. For Brazil, from the late i96os to the
late I98os, the Non-Proliferation Treaty was one of the clearest examples of
what it termed the 'freezing of world power'-although it moved steadily
through the subsequent period towards rapprochement with Argentina and
membership of the major arms control regimes including, in I998, the NPT."
In the case of India, the non-proliferation regime epitomized the impediment
posed by a hierarchically organized regime to its foreign policy. It exemplified
" Brazil remains concerned both to continue its technological development in this area and to protect its
autonomous enrichment and reprocessing capabilities from further international restriction.
I0
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
discrimination between the haves and have-nots and represented a block on
both upward mobility and technological progress. But the nuclear case also
illustrates the way in which the country's size and geopohtical importance
enabled a successful challenge to the regime. Although the costs were significant (regionally and in terms of relations with Washington), India has been able
to gain implicit acceptance as a nuclear power. Having achieved that goal it is,
of course, anxious to be seen as a 'responsible nuclear power' and has a shared
interest in blocking further proliferation.
The fact that these four countries are second-tier states also means that their
pohcies towards international institutions inevitably have a double-sided quality.
On the one hand, they may be pressed to use institutions to fulfil some of the
classic power-related functions, above all to signal reassurance to weaker states,
especially within their regions. The clearest example of this is the shift in Chinese
policy towards regional security institutions and its desire to use institutions to
provide reassurance to weaker states, especially with regard to its relations with
ASEAN. On the other hand, their continued status as second-tier states faced
by a very powerful United States means that they share an interest in
institutions as a means of taming the power of the most powerful.
In the first place, institutions can constrain the powerful through established
rules and procedures. The fundamental goal is to tie down Gulliver in as many
ways as possible, however thin the individual institutional threads may be. It is
therefore not surprising that Brazil and India should be the fourth and fifth
most active complainants under the WTO dispute settlement mechanism. Nor
is it especially puzzling that Brazil, China and India should wish to use international institutions to resist attempts by the US to promote new norms on the
use of force or the conditionality of sovereignty, or the right to use force to
promote regime change. Second, institutions provide weaker states with political space to build new coalitions in order to try to affect emerging norms in
ways that are congruent with their interests, and to counterbalance or at least
deflect the preferences and policies of the most powerful. The activist coali-
tional policies of Brazil and India within the WTO, highlighted by Narhkar,
provide a very good example, most notably in terms of the G20 coalition
created at Cancun in 2003.
Third, institutions open up 'voice opportunities' that allow relatively weak
states to make known their interests and to bid for political support in the
broader marketplace of ideas. For much of the I99os, all these countries adopted
generally defensive positions in relation to the liberal norms being pressed by
the industrialized West: all four in relation to humanitarian intervention; Brazil
and India in terms of ever more far-reaching norms of economic liberalization,
especially within the context of the WTO. Narlikar lays particular emphasis on
India's reputation for defensiveness and its tradition as a tough, inflexible and,
in the view of some, ideological negotiator. The balance struck between
genuine internalization, pragmatic accommodation and resistance has varied by
issue, by country and across time. What is notable is the way in which these
II
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
countries have become more proactive-for example, using the language of
democracy and representativeness to push for the reform of international
institutions; or using the language of economic liberalism as a stick with which
to attack US and European protectionism. Both Brazil and India have
mobilized claims for greater representational fairness (as with membership of
the Security Council or decision-making within the WTO) and distributional
justice (as with Brazil's promotion of a global hunger fund). However, it is
much less clear how far any of these countries have moved in terms of
becoming producers of the ideas that will shape conceptions of global order in
the future. This matters for many reasons, not least because, while state-based
power is undoubtedly hegemonically structured around the US, the power of
ideas, values and culture is potentially more open and contested.
Relations with the United States: bandwagoning or pragmatic
accommodation?
As we have seen, some analysts believe that the sheer extent of US power not
only precludes effective opposition but also increases the incentives to bandwagon with Washington. As Wohlforth puts it: 'The only options available to
second-tier states are to bandwagon with the polar power (either explicitly or
implicitly) or, at least, to take no action that could incur its focused enmity.'12
There are three motives behind bandwagoning:I3 first, by aligning with the
dominant state, a weaker state hopes to avoid challenges or to divert them
elsewhere; second, a state aligns with the dominant state in order to share in the
spoils of war or of other forms of conflict (for example, securing access to
Middle East oil on the back of support for US policy); and third, a state aligns
with the dominant state in order to secure other political or economic
advantages (for example, Russia trading support on counterterrorism in return
for muted criticism of its domestic or regional policies).
The logic of bandwagoning has played a major role in recent US foreign
policy thinking and practice. Hard unilateralism and the emphasis on the threat
and use of military power can make sense only on the assumption that the
dominant response of weaker states and other actors will be straightforward
submission (shock and awe) or the desire to negotiate. But the cultivation of
bandwagoning, especially towards important second-tier states, remains important as the failures of a hard, unilateralist 'we can do it alone' policy become
ever more evident. As we enter a period of hegemonic decompression, what
options are available to Washington? One (very unlikely) one is a wholehearted embrace of liberal multilateralism. A second is to re-engage with
institutions but at the same time to try to reshape those institutions in ways that
more closely reflect current US interests. The third is to refocus attention on a
long-standing element of US foreign policy, namely the construction of a hub12 Wohlforth, 'The stability of a unipolar world', p. 25.
I3 Stephen M. Walt, The origins of alliances (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, I987), pp. 19-21.
12
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
and-spoke system of cultivated relations with major emerging or regional
powers.I4
It is certainly the case that for Brazil, Russia, India and China, the concentration of power in and around the United States has been central in shaping
their views of the system and of the options available to them. It is also true that
this concentration has created strong incentives to avoid the focused enmity of
the US and to seek coincidences of interest when available-out of a concern
for both issue-specific advantages and power-related interests. And yet it is not
clear that their behaviour overall can be usefully characterized in terms of
bandwagoning. On the one hand, the category incorporates a range of policies
from clear alignment to pragmatic accommodation. On the other, the salience
of bandwagoning as a motivation for policy is fluid and varies across time and
issue area.
Among the four states under consideration, Brazilian policy is the furthest
away from such a policy. It is true that bandwagoning behaviour has been a
feature of US-Brazilian relations at particular periods (notably from 1942 to I945
and from I964 to 1967). But for most of the post-I945 period the relationship
has not been especially close and has been characterized both by real clashes of
interest (especially over economic and trade issues), by deep and persistent diver-
gences in the way in which the two countries view the international system,
and by a recurrent sense of mutual frustration. 5 As Lima and Hirst argue, more
recent policy has aimed at prudent coexistence, possible collaboration and
minimal collision, but has shied away from any kind of special relationship.
There is a striking parallel in the overall character of US-Indian and USBrazilian relations through the Cold War, especially in terms of the role of
mutual misperception. Cohen's summary characterization of US-Indian
relations could certainly be applied to Brazil:
The United States and India have clearly grown distant over the years, not only
because of abundant misperceptions on both sides but also because of fundamental
differences on the best way to peacefully organize the international system, the nature
of the Soviet Union, the virtue (or sins) of alliances, and above all, the degree to which
in Indian eyes the United States resisted India's emergence as a major power.i6
Differences between Washington and Delhi continued through the I99os
and moves towards rapprochement were hindered both by the I998 nuclear test
and by the closeness of US relations with Pakistan, strengthened of course by
I4 This pattern has been consistently dominant in US policy towards Asia. It was also central to US foreign
policy in a previous period of imperial overstretch, namely the late i96os and early I970os, in the idea
that US interests could be protected through the devolution of 'responsibility' to 'regional influentials'
in the form of the Nixon Doctrine. See Robert Litwak, Detente and the Nixon Doctrine: American foreign
policy and the pursuit of stability 1969-1975 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, I984).
'5 For a fuller analysis see Andrew Hurrell, 'The United States and Brazil: comparative reflections', in
Monica Hirst, The United States and Brazil: the long road of unmet expectations (New York: Routledge,
2005), pp. 73-Io8.
I6 Stephen P. Cohen, India, emerging power (Washington DC: Brookings Institution, 200I), pp. 287-98.
I3
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
the demands of the so-called war on terror. Against this, we have seen the
recent emergence of a language of 'natural allies' and 'strategic partnership' as
well as a number of concrete agreements, most notably the July 2005 nuclear
agreement and India's vote to report Iran to the UNSC. However, it is far too
early to talk of any fundamental realignment; there are obvious advantages to
India of developing and exploiting a wider range of foreign policy
relationships, and, as Narlikar notes, there are also important continuities in the
pattern of India's foreign policy thinking and conduct. It has certainly not
dropped its engagement with developing countries, bilaterally and collectively
In the case of China, Foot highlights the diversity of positions within th
country and argues that pragmatic accommodation best characterizes Chines
policy towards the United States. On the one hand, China has sought to accom
modate itself to US power and to seek coincidences of interest. It has criticize
but acquiesced in US policies with which it has fundamentally disagreed-Ira
most notably-and has been less strident than Brazil and India in opposing US
preferences within the WTO. But this has been counterbalanced by a
broadening range of stances designed both to retain flexibility if relations with
Washington should deteriorate and to lay the groundwork for a more active
foreign policy in the future. MacFarlane notes the move in the period sinc
200I away from an emphasis on the importance of re-establishing multipolarity
and towards an acceptance of the unassailability of US primacy. This has led t
a hard-headed recognition of the need to avoid confrontation on matters o
vital interest to the US (as with Iraq), combined with a willingness to engage
hard bargaining and issue linkage, to cultivate as broad a range of ties as
possible, and to defend immediate interests wherever possible, especially in
relation to its immediate neighbourhood. Assessments of America's threshold
of tolerance have become one of the most crucial elements of foreign policy
(best illustrated in the case of Russian policy towards Iran).
Two final points should be noted. Bandwagoning is sometimes seen as an
unproblematic 'option'. And yet it is notable how few countries in the world
possess the resources and even the potential capacity to make such a special
relationship work in their favour-dense administration-to-administration ties
(including in the military and intelligence sectors), an embedded habit of
consultation, and a broad structure of social interconnections. In the present
context, one of the most interesting signs of potential change is the growth of
transnational ties with the Indian American community, and the attempt by the
Indian government to exploit these as part of the relationship (including, for
example, in the aftermath of its nuclear test). Second, whatever the incentives
to seek productive bargaining with Washington, all of these countries have
experienced the difficulties of accommodating themselves to this particular
hegemon. The United States has never been an easy country with which to
bandwagon, and this is especially true in the period since 2oo00i-a period in
which it has emphasized its own inalienable right to security even at the cost of
the insecurity of others; upheld a traditional rigid conception of its own
14
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
sovereignty, while at the same time arguing that the sovereignty of others
should be conditional; and proclaimed a strident moralism and a profoundly
revisionist attitude to the structure of international society.
A move towards soft balancing?
It is not difficult to find recurrent statements, albeit varying in intensity,
expressing unhappiness with the unipolar structure of global politics and the
desirability of a more balanced system-'to increase, if only by a margin, the
degree of multipolarity in the world', as the Brazilian foreign minister recently
put it.17 Theorists are correct to stress the absence of balancing behaviour in a
'hard' traditional sense, and practitioners would no doubt add that any such
behaviour runs counter both to their interests and to any realistic understanding of viable policy. But what of more subtle forms of balancing behaviour
such as soft or constrained balancing? Such behaviour does not involve direct
attempts to confront or constrain the dominant state through the creation of
military alliances (external balancing) or through the build-up of military power
(internal balancing). Instead, as Paul notes, it involves other forms of cooperation: ententes, informal understandings, ad hoc cooperative exercises or
collaboration in regional or international institutions.'8 Its purpose is to complicate and raise the costs of US policies in international institutions (especially
by denying legitimacy), to challenge dominant US preferences, and to
withhold the effective (as opposed to formal or rhetorical) cooperation on
which the fulfilment of US foreign policy goals depends. For Pape, its purpose
is to use non-military tools 'to delay, frustrate and undermine aggressive uni-
lateral US policies'.'9 It is by no means a new phenomenon; indeed, it is
familiar to anyone who has studied the foreign policy options of states within a
great power sphere of influence.20
To what extent is it accurate or useful to view the recent policies of Brazil,
India, China and Russia, and especially the growth of different forms of
relations among them, in terms of soft or constrained balancing?
The critics of soft balancing are correct in arguing that not all behaviour that
looks like balancing is in fact driven by balance-of-power motivations. There
may be many good economic, regional or domestic political reasons why
second-tier states seek to collaborate with each other. Unless their actions are
in some way responses to US power, then it certainly does not make sense t
invoke balance-of-power theory. It is also important to highlight both th
degree of accommodation with the United States (as noted in the previous
section), the limits to the cooperation among second-tier states (as in China
17 Celso Amorim, interview in Folha de Sao Paulo, I6 May 2005.
18 T. V. Paul, 'Soft balancing in the age of US primacy', International Security 30: I, Summer 2005, pp. 58-9.
I9 Robert A. Pape, 'Soft balancing against the United States', International Security 30: I, Summer 2005, p. I0.
20 See Andrew Hurrell, 'The United States and Latin America: neorealism re-examined', in Ngaire
Woods, ed., Explaining international relations since 1945 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, I996), p. I63
I5
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
resistance to reform of the Security Council or the relative thinness of the
allegedly 'strategic' ties between India and Brazil), and the continuation of
underlying suspicion among such states (as in the case of Russia and China).
However, those who take a sceptical view of soft balancing risk setting the
bar too high and underplaying the role of US power and US policies in shaping
policy across a range of apparently very diverse issue areas. The relevance and
utility of balance-of-power theory are not limited to those cases where
unbalanced power poses a 'direct security challenge to other states'.2' The
problem of unbalanced power is not that it leads inexorably to a military threat;
it is rather that radically unbalanced power will permit the powerful to 'lay
down the law' to the less powerful, to skew the terms of cooperation in its own
favour, to impose its own values and ways of doing things, and to undermine
the procedural rules on which stable and legitimate cooperation must inevitably depend. It is for this reason that the perceived need to 'contain' the power
of the United States does form a very important element of the policies of
Brazil, Russia, India and China in many areas and on many issues that sceptics
would like to consign to the arena of 'normal diplomatic bargaining'. The
politics of Brazil and India in the WTO is very directly related to the systemic
concentration of power and is not simply a product of issue-specific interests.
Finally, much of the argument depends on the significance that one attaches
to questions of legitimacy and symbolic action. For the sceptics, 'soft balancing
is not an argument about symbolic action. It applies only to policies that promise
to do something to increase constraints on or shift power against the United
States.'22 It is, however, only a very narrow and inadequate view of power that
can so easily dismiss the degree to which sustained US power depends on the
successful cultivation of legitimacy. As Aron noted: 'Either a great power will
not tolerate equals, and then must proceed to the last degree of empire, or else
it consents to stand first among sovereign units, and must win acceptance for
such pre-eminence.'23 Legitimacy and symbolic action are central to the winning of such acceptance.
Economic development and foreign policy options
In all of the four cases, the imperatives of economic development are starkly
evident, both in their relative salience within overall government policy and in
the importance of specific objectives-the importance of raw materials and
energy in Chinese foreign policy; Brazil's desire to diversify export markets;
the importance of increasing US and western foreign investment in India; or
the role of energy exports as one of the most crucial bargaining tools within
Russian foreign policy. In the case of China, economic success has been built
2I Stephen G. Brooks and William C. Wohlforth, 'Hard times for soft balancing', International Security 30:
I, Summer 2005, p. 103.
22 Brooks and Wohlforth, 'Hard times for soft balancing', p. 82.
23 Raymond Aron, Peace and war: a theory of international relations (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, I966),
p. 70.
i6
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
around integration into the global economy, and this success has provided
many opportunities for bargaining and has acted as a restraint on US power. In
addition, over time, the Chinese 'model' may be seen increasingly as a soft
power resource.24 In other cases, it is the economic constraints that are most
crucial-as with the heavy focus on domestic consolidation in Russia under
Putin and the overriding imperative of regenerating the economy and restoring
the effective role of the state; or the continued high level of external economic
vulnerability faced by the Brazilian government.
It is, however, difficult to establish any clear-cut and consistent connections
between specific models of economic development, or even degrees of economic liberalization, on the one hand, and the choice of particular foreign policy
options on the other.
First, for all the talk about the imperatives of globalization and the pressure
to adapt to those imperatives, it is the continued variation of development
trajectories that is most striking. In all of these cases powerful external pressures
for change have come up against very deep-rooted sets of domestic social,
political and economic structures and very distinctive national traditions, leading to developmental trajectories that continue to vary very significantly. In the
I99os many discussions of globalization concentrated on a stark and unhelpful
dichotomy between fusion and fragmentation, or between convergence and
revolt. Although the systemic pressures associated with globalization are very
powerful, it is crucial to unpack and deconstruct the complex processes of break-
down and adaptation that are occurring within individual societies, especially
large and complex societies. When this is done, the intuitively powerful idea of
homogenization itself breaks down as it becomes clear that outcomes conform
neither to anything resembling a simple liberal 'model' nor to a simple rejection of that model. Again, the 'large and complex country' category is relevant:
while external norms are indeed being internalized, this process results not in
conformity with some general model but rather in new configurations of
national beliefs and new patterns of national self-understanding. In terms of
foreign policy, this reinforces the argument that policy choices cannot be read
off as a simple function of systemic pressures.
Second, in all of these four cases, we should note the continued degree of
state control over foreign policy. A clear implication of liberal theory is that
economic and political liberalization should lead to greater pluralism. We should
expect to see a significant move away from the strong statism that previously
characterized all of these countries. Foreign policy strategies should be influenced, if
not shaped, by the increasing societal pluralism that has accompanied economic
and political liberalization (generating industrial groups, political parties, social
movements and NGOs, scientific and academic communities). Narlikar
examines this claim explicitly in the case of India, but concludes that the actual
influence of interest groups, even on trade policy, is limited. Lima and Hirst
24 See Anthony Payne, The global politics of unequal development (Basingstoke: Palgrave, 2005), pp. 95-I00.
I7
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Andrew Hurrell
highlight the increased politicization of foreign policy in Brazil. But, thus far, it
is the limits to greater pluralism that are their most evident aspect.
Third, although inwardly oriented development models were strongly
associated with nationalist foreign policies in the years after I945, the move
towards economic liberalization and greater integration in the global economy
does not appear to have a clear foreign policy correlate. In Brazil, Lula's assertive and activist foreign policy has gone hand in hand with an extremely
orthodox macroeconomic policy at home. In their different ways, both India
and China indicate how nationalism and economic liberalization can coexist-
whether spontaneously or as a result of active cultivation on the part of
government. A strongly nationalist foreign policy may be consciously used t
bolster legitimacy at home (as with China), or to compensate for the absence
radicalism at home (as in Brazil). In the case of India, Narlikar highlights th
importance of a domestic political culture that supports grandstanding and nay-
saying abroad. Success is arguably what matters most. The goals of seeking
greater influence and a more prominent role in the world or in the region
remain; liberal economic integration provides a means of achieving those goal
Hence a willingness to challenge comes from the renewed confidence that
economic success brings. To argue in this way does not imply acceptance o
the neo-realist belief that all economic power will inevitably be tied to a
politico-military challenge. Rather, it is to suggest that all states, but especially
very large states, balance economic welfare and development with considera
tions of power and autonomy. Power matters because, even within the conte
of continued market-liberal economic reform within a mostly market-liber
global economy, the scope for real clashes of interest and of values remains very
wide. Who gets how much? Who sets the rules of the global economy? Who
values are embodied in those rules?
Conclusion
At the start of this article, I suggested various reasons for taking Brazil, Russia,
India and China as a group. Two other similarities need to be stressed. The first
is a shared sense of uncertainty, especially about the behaviour of the United
States. It is, therefore, hardly surprising that hedging should be a very visible
characteristic of the foreign policy behaviour of second-tier states. A second,
and maybe more surprising, characteristic is a shared sense of vulnerability. Size
may increase options, and each of these countries may have a belief in its
'natural' right to an influential international role. But all of them remain acutely
aware of their vulnerability. The precise character of the problems varies from
case to case, as does the balance between vulnerabilities rooted respectively in
the system as a whole, in the nastiness of regions and neighbourhoods, and in
domestic cohesion and state capacity.
On the other side, the articles that follow serve to highlight that this is an
extremely disparate group of states. Russia is a power that has been in decline
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Hegemony, liberalism and global order
for at least the past 20 years, and whose foreign policy has centred on trying to
arrest that decline. It is far from clear whether it will succeed. China is in a
league of its own. It is not simply that its power resources and potentia
development are of a different order; it is also that its power has been combined
with a long-term sense of where it would like to be and that, as a state, it has to
date maintained a significant degree of strength and coherence. It has also
shown awareness of the degree to which its rising power is potentially viewed
as threatening by others. For the foreseeable future India and Brazil may be best
seen not as great powers but as increasingly activist and influential intermediate
states.
Brazil and India are in a different category for a further reason. On the one
hand, they can be seen-and like to see themselves-as potential major
powers, both within their regions and more generally. But on the other hand,
they have identified themselves more specifically as developing countries and
have understood their foreign policy options through the prism of NorthSouth relations. This has been a persistent theme in the case of India; in the case
of Brazil it has been a more ambiguous one, but one that is clearly in the
ascendant under the present government. But is the language of Third
Worldism and southern solidarity simply a hangover from the past? Or is it an
interest-driven strategy that reflects a particular set of contingent interests (as on
trade issues within the WTO)? Or is it reflective of a deeper set of beliefs,
interests and commitments? If so, what happens if that 'developing country
identity' comes into conflict with the 'aspiring great power identity'? In both
cases this duality speaks to the tension between an aspiration to international
influence and a continued sense of vulnerability, and to the difficulty of having
to defend oneself against an increasingly intrusive world that challenges oldestablished national ways of acting and thinking. It also speaks to the contested,
and as yet unfinished, debates as to how far these countries should embrace a
liberal, globalized order and what the actual space for autonomy might be in
the face of the changing character of the global economy on the one hand, and
US hegemonic power on the other.
I9
This content downloaded from 132.174.251.250 on Mon, 16 Jul 2018 00:24:27 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Descargar