Hacienda Pública Española / Revista de Economía Pública, 196-(1/2011): 37-63 © 2011, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods: Blockbuster art exhibitions* EVA VICENTE** PABLO DE FRUTOS University of Valladolid Recibido: Abril, 2010 Aceptado: Diciembre, 2010 Abstract In recent years a growing number of studies have started to apply non-market valuation methods to es­ timate the economic value of cultural goods. The majority of these studies use stated preference tech­ niques, such as the contingent valuation method. This study discusses the application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of a specific type of cultural good: special exhibitions. The em­ pirical work focuses on the touring exhibition the ‘Ages of Mankind’, one of the first and most repre­ sentative examples of a blockbuster art exhibition in Spain. This is the first time, as far as we know, that this method has been applied to a large temporary exhibition and is one of the few applications of this method in the valuation of cultural goods. Keywords: Blockbuster arts exhibitions, non-market valuation, revealed preferences, travel cost method, cultural economics. JEL classification: H41, D60, Z11 1. Introduction In recent decades temporary exhibitions have grown enormously in terms of frequency and importance, leading to a boom in this type of cultural supply (Heilbrun and Gray, 1993; ∗ Authors gratefully acknowledge research funding for this study from the Directorate General for Cultural Herita­ ge, Regional Ministry of Culture and Tourism of Castile and Leon, Spain. We also wish to thank ‘Las Edades del Hombre’ Foundation for permitting visitor surveys to be undertaken during the 2006 edition in Ciudad Rodrigo, Spain. We are also very grateful to two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. ** University of Valladolid, Department of Applied Economics. Eva Vicente. e-mail: [email protected]; Pablo de Frutos. e-mail: [email protected] 38 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS Frey and Busenhart, 1996; Frey, 2000; Johnson, 2003). Certain exhibitions, mainly destined for a wide domestic and/or international audience, have become significant cultural events attracting thousands of visitors. This is true for blockbuster exhibitions which, due to partic­ ular attributes, have reached a relevant position in the tourist and recreation choices of many people. Nevertheless, despite the success of these activities, their utility and social profitability are still being debated. Policy makers and managers of cultural institutions are becoming in­ creasingly interested in evaluating and measuring the social benefits gained from these ini­ tiatives, although the few studies carried out to date have focused on measuring their eco­ nomic impact in terms of income and employment (Wall and Roberts, 1985; Stanley et al., 2000; Skinner, 2006; Vicente et al., 2007), rather than the effects on social welfare by esti­ mating changes in visitor consumer surplus. Unlike the former approach, the latter focuses on measuring the utility derived by individuals from the cultural goods or services or, in equivalent terms, the value these goods or services are given from the maximum amount that visitors are willing to pay to enjoy them. The market is the usual mechanism through which individual preferences for different goods and services are revealed, providing the necessary information to estimate their de­ mand, required prior to the valuation process. However, the public-good nature of many of the values and services derived from cultural goods and the presence of externalities in their production and consumption (Peacock, 1969; Netzer, 1978; Frey and Pommerehne, 1989; Albi, 2003; Vicente, 2007) makes it impossible to measure them merely through the market, forcing economists to seek alternative methods to assess their value (Cuccia and Signorello, 2002; Poor and Smith, 2004). The main difficulty is that the value currently attached to cul­ tural goods as well as the nature of the demand for their products and experiences are com­ plex phenomena, which go beyond their mere use value or direct consumption. These goods or services also generate a further series of values referred to as non-use or passive-use, since they are independent from their use or present consumption. These potential sources of util­ ity have been widely recognised and classified in the literature on the topic into three basic categories: option value (the value which non-current users attribute to the possibility of being able to consume cultural goods and services in the future), existence value (the value attributed to the mere existence of the goods, regardless of any current or future use) and be­ quest value (the value citizens derive from knowing that the goods will be available for use by future generations). Usually, none of these values are available in monetary terms. In the case of use value, although cultural goods and services are often traded in markets, the con­ ditions under which they are usually provided –free of cost, subsidised or, in general, prices not reflecting the cost of supplying them– means that the market proves insufficient as a way to gauge true public preferences regarding such goods (Greffe, 1990; Mourato and Mazanti, 2002). Determining non-use value proves extremely complex, due to the intangible nature and public good status, entailing the lack of markets where value can be estimated. To overcome these difficulties, different techniques have been developed that allow the economic value of these types of goods and services to be estimated. Such techniques, gen­ Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 39 erally known as non-market valuation methods, have been successfully applied in other areas in recent decades, particularly in the field of environmental resources. Despite the similari­ ties between these goods and cultural goods, application of these techniques in the latter in­ stance is relatively recent and comparatively few studies have ever been carried out (Pearce et al., 2002), mainly using stated preference models, such as the contingent valuation method1. In contrast, the application of techniques based on revealed preferences such as the travel cost method (hereinafter TCM) has been very limited. This is due to the restrictive na­ ture of the assumptions upon which this technique is based, as well as the nature of cultural goods and services, which limit the potential use of this approach (Greffe, 1990; Frey, 2000; Ready and Navrud, 2002; Mourato and Mazzanti, 2002). Yet, the advantages gained from working with revealed preferences, which allow modelling of consumer behaviour from data obtained in non-contingent situations, support the use of this technique to measure the value of cultural goods and highlight the need to undertake further research in this area (Boter et al., 2005: 20). In recent years, TCM has gained in importance as a valuation method in cultural eco­ nomics and has been applied in certain recent studies (Snowball, 2008: 78). This technique has been used, for instance, in the areas of museums (Martin, 1994), the theatre (Forrest, et al., 2000), and built heritage (Poor and Smith, 2004; Alberini and Longo, 2006; Parumog et al., 2006; Chen et al., 2008). These studies apply the TCM to measure the use value of these goods and services and in some instances, combined with other methods, to estimate their total economic value. In light of the foregoing, this study discusses application of the TCM to estimate the consumer surplus associated with special exhibitions. We conducted an empirical study for Kyrios, the thirteenth exhibition of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ (Las Edades del Hombre). These exhibitions are a series of blockbuster exhibitions displaying religious art and are devoted to the movable cultural heritage of the Catholic Church in the region of Castile and Leon (Spain). As far as the authors know, this is the first time this method has been applied to a large temporary or blockbuster exhibition2. This article is outlined as follows: firstly, section two is dedicated to presenting the most important characteristics of the study case; section three then moves on to discuss the travel cost method with its associated problems and the source of data; section four is devoted to analysing results from the demand model, estimated through the zonal travel cost method, and the associated consumer surplus. Finally, a discussion and several conclusions of this re­ search are presented. 2. Study Case: Kyrios, the blockbuster exhibition of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ in Ciudad Rodrigo Nowadays, large-scale special exhibitions or blockbusters are considered activities with cultural and social relevance and prestige attached to them. Their welcome by the public, 40 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS media impact and temporary nature make these cultural events highly attractive to promot­ ers, leading to an increase in the number thereof and securing the efforts and interests of var­ ious public and private institutions (Frey, 2000; Johnson, 2003). Their success lies in their special characteristics, such as limited duration and the fact they are exceptional and unique events3 (Belcher, 1994; Tobelem, 2005, 2006). These kinds of cultural activities make art more accessible for the public to enjoy in two main ways (Heilbrun and Gray, 1993; Skinner, 2006): a ‘concentration effect’ and a ‘distri­ bution effect’. They allow for the collection of a large amount of artwork based upon a theme, an artist, movement or historical period; greater than could possibly be seen at one time anywhere else. The display of the artwork together also has a powerful aesthetic impact and creates a more lasting impression on visitors. These exhibitions allow cultural products of large dimensions and great visual impact to be taken to places which are often far away from large collections or museums, and are not themselves traditional cultural centres. Given their nature, the temporary exhibitions attract experts and those interested in what is offered on display, satisfying special or particular preferences and allowing specific demand niches to be explored. These events are also featured by their ability to attract new audiences (Frey and Meier, 2006), given that they manage to draw in people who have never before shown an interest in art and would rarely visit a museum4 (Fernández and Prieto, 2004). This ‘pop­ ularisation’ of art, as Frey points out (2000: 93), may not be of much interest to certain artists or art lovers, but it should be considered a remarkable achievement from the point of view that it responds to individual preferences. Given the variety of factors involved in their organisation, these ‘mega-exhibitions’ have complex production processes and are relatively expensive (Heilbrun and Gray, 1993; Stanley et al., 2000; Skinner, 2006), generally requiring public support. The exhibitions also rely heavily on collaborative and cooperative relationships, not only for financing but also for communication purposes (Tobelem, 2005). Given their nature, the special exhibitions provide potentially important economic benefits for the host institution and other agents involved, as well as for the area or region where they are held (Heilbrun and Gray, 1993; Frey, 2000; Tobelem, 2006), all depending on the magnitude and the scope of the exhibition (Vi­ cente, et al., 2007). As with the majority of cultural goods and services, blockbuster exhibitions can be con­ sidered a quasi-public good: they are non rival goods –the visit to the exhibition is an ex­ perience which can be shared by a large number of people during the period it is shown and many people can visit at once5 (Belcher, 1994) –and potentially excludable goods6. The visit provides significant benefits to the user: the enjoyment or pleasure experienced while viewing the exhibits (aesthetic benefits), entertainment (recreational benefits) and knowl­ edge (educational benefits). The value and quality of the experience provided by these types of cultural activities are such that the public is willing to visit en masse and also pay for the privilege. Together with their significant use values, blockbuster exhibitions are also ex­ pected to generate a non-use value, although the relative importance thereof is likely to be much less than in the case of other cultural goods. A blockbuster exhibition is an exception­ Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 41 al and unique cultural event of a limited duration, meaning that there is little point dis­ cussing the existence of option or bequest values in relation to goods of this nature which, by definition, are linked to the availability of a good or service in the future. It is true, how­ ever, that some citizens may attach an existence value to such an activity, deriving mainly from a feeling of pride and the image of prestige which hosting such an event confers on the town or area where it is held. The existence value in this case would refer to the value allocated to holding the exhibition (a cultural dissemination project) regardless of whether or not it was to be visited. Such value differs from that allocated to the exhibited goods. Conservation of such exhibits is independent from the exhibition and once the exhibition has concluded they may be visited at their respective place of origin or where they are usu­ ally displayed. The series of temporary exhibitions of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ is a clear example of suc­ cess in the diffusion of culture, the media impact and the social and economic repercussions that such activities can have. This is evident in the 15 exhibitions held since 1988, which have been open to the public for 100 months and have displayed approximately 3,700 pieces, with accumulated number of visits exceeding nine million people (see Table 1). These fig­ ures endorse the exhibitions collectively as one of the most successful cultural events both in Spain and on an international scale, considering their continuity in time and space, and that rather than running out of steam they have managed to maintain the interest and expec­ tations of the public with each new exhibition. ‘Ages of Mankind’ is a series of religious art exhibitions, devoted to the movable cultur­ al heritage of the Catholic Church in Castile and Leon (Spain), and held in the region’s cathedrals since 1988. They encompass religion and culture, are highly original in form and purpose, and different to other temporary exhibitions held in Spain or abroad (García, 2000). This project has been led by the diocese of Castile and Leon, through ‘Las Edades del Hom­ bre’ Foundation and relies on the financial support of different institutions and regional agents including the regional government of Castile and Leon, different regional financial institutions and local authorities of the cities and provinces where the different exhibitions have been held. Further financing needs for the exhibitions have been met by income ob­ tained from the sale of catalogues and other such products. No income has been generated from entrance fees as the visits are free of charge. The objectives pursued with this series of exhibitions go beyond the exhibition of the rich art of the Catholic Church in Castile and Leon. Through an innovative project of valori­ sation and diffusion of religious cultural heritage, a range of images, paintings, sculptures and other objects have been sought out and presented in a secular framework to retransmit their religious and cultural message. The fact that the exhibitions are more than just mere artistic representations is one of the main reasons behind their initial success and has helped to keep the project going over the years. However, this is not the only reason for the success of the ‘Ages of Mankind’; among other factors are the originality and the novelty of the initial project and the na­ 42 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS ture of the exhibits themselves. The ‘Ages of Mankind’ has marked a milestone in Spain in terms of museum innovation. The design of the exhibitions breaks with traditional methods of displaying artwork according to artistic style and following museum crite­ ria, using storyboards which display the work in context. The chosen pieces are select­ ed for each exhibition not only for their artistic value, but also for their facility to com­ municate the thread of ideas to the visitor providing form and content to each unique exhibition. Other reasons for the exhibitions’ success include the historical and artistic wealth of the cultural heritage of Castile and Leon, allowing a selection of exceptional pieces to be chosen for each occasion, most of which have never been displayed before. The use of the region’s cathedrals to display the exhibits also adds greater value to a high quality cultural product, as are all the exhibited pieces. Other causes, not directly linked to the exhibits, relate to the apt timing of the exhibitions within a context of growing cultural demand and in particular the boom in cultural tourism, a trend in re­ cent decades. The final factor influencing the success of the exhibition to a great ex­ tent, is that entrance is free. Far from devaluating the exhibition, this has helped it to fulfil its primary objective. Visitors were able to appreciate that exhibits belonging to their common history and culture were on display and it did not therefore seem right to charge an entrance fee. Another objective pursued by the organisers of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ has also been achieved, namely that the public would see exhibited pieces as something belonging to them, identifying with them, and valuing them as their own property (García, 2000). Twenty years of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ has allowed this series of exhibitions to be re­ ferred to as the largest cultural project (in the area of exhibition policies) undertaken in Spain, considering the extraordinary length of time it has been running (Vicente et al., 2007). However, in the beginning this series of exhibitions was designed with more modest aims: the initial project solely contemplated three large exhibitions which would be held in the cathedrals of Valladolid, Burgos and Leon, respectively. The repeated success of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ led to the initial project being continued after it had originally finished, with the creation of an identically-named foundation commit­ ted to organising an exhibition in each diocese of the region which had not yet held one of the exhibitions. During the first stage of the project a total of 13 exhibitions were held in Castile and Leon and two in Antwerp and New York. Once the ‘Ages of Mankind’ exhibi­ tions had passed through the cathedrals of the region, a new stage of the project was started, which took the exhibition to other locations in Castile and Leon, using new exhibition spaces such as basilicas and co-cathedrals, starting in Ponferrada with the exhibition ‘Yo, camino’. The main characteristics and results of the exhibitions held to date are detailed below in Table 1. The exhibition used for this study, ‘Kyrios’, was the thirteenth exhibition of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ series, concluding a significant stage of this cultural project which had been tour­ ing the different cathedrals of Castile and Leon since 1988. 43 Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods Table 1 THE ‘AGES OF MANKIND’ EXHIBITIONS (1988-2010) Exhibitions Location El arte en la Iglesia de Castilla y León Valladolid Libros y documentos en la Iglesia Burgos de Castilla y León La música en la Iglesia de Castilla León y León El contrapunto y su morada Salamanca Flandes y Castilla y León Antwerp La ciudad de seis pisos El Burgo de Osma Memoria y esplendores Palencia Encrucijadas Astorga Remembranza Zamora Time to Hope New York El Árbol de la Vida Segovia Testigos Ávila Kyrios Ciudad Rodrigo Yo Camino Ponferrada Paisaje Interior Soria Total − Year Duration Exhibition Number (months) displayed of visits 1988-89 5 209 1,050,000 1990 6 482 500,000 1991-92 1993-94 1995 1997 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2006 2007 2009-10 10 11 3 7 7 6 7 2 8 7 6 7 8 219 220 182 182 305 305 374 100 301 278 200 131 208 980,000 1,303,000 95,000 458,757 612,000 460,000 510,000 205,207 858,977 859,859 550,253 407,040 407,377 − 100 3,696 9,257,470 Source: Created by us based on data from “Las Edades del Hombre” Foundation website. Kyrios was organised and coordinated by two institutions: ‘Las Edades del Hombre’ Foundation and the regional government, through the ‘Siglo para las Artes’ Foundation in Castile and Leon. The exhibition relied on funding from both institutions together with spon­ sorship funds from Caja España savings bank and the Historic Heritage Foundation of Castile and Leon channelled through the ‘Siglo para las Artes’ Foundation. In addition, ad­ vertising and marketing expenses were supported by the Society for Promotion of Tourism in Castile and Leon (Sociedad de Promoción del Turismo de Castilla y León). The total cost of Kyrios amounted to more than 3.7 million euros. The exhibition opened on 9 June 2006 for a period of six months, until 10 December 2006. The exhibition reflected its title Kyrios (Lord) and the exhibition’s storyboard was or­ ganised accordingly in five chapters, concentrating on the figure and life of Christ. Two hun­ dred pieces from the eleven dioceses of Castile and Leon were displayed, in particular those from the diocese of Ciudad Rodrigo, as well as eight pieces from Portuguese civil and eccle­ siastical institutions, 90% of all pieces never having been shown before. The exhibition spanned the entire period from the 10th century to the 20th century, and included artists such as Gregorio Fernández, Diego and Gil de Siloé, Pedro de Mena, Juan de Arfe, Fernando Gal­ lego, Pedro Berruguete, Luis de Morales, Luca Giordano and Alonso Cano, among others. 44 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS As in many of the previous exhibitions, the number of visits exceeded initial forecasts, the final figure reaching 550,253 visits. Kyrios became the seventh most visited exhibition of the eleven held in the cathedrals of Castile and Leon, with visitor numbers surpassing even those of exhibitions held in provincial capitals such as Zamora and Burgos. 3. Methods and data 3.1. Methods These are a number of reasons why TCM is the approach selected to estimate the con­ sumer surplus associated with the cultural visits to the Kyrios exhibition. Firstly, it is one of the most popular valuation techniques for measuring the value of a non-market resource (In­ hyuck, 2007). Secondly, TCM is a suitable method to assess temporary exhibitions since, given their characteristics (a unique event within a limited timeframe) the use value dominates as opposed to other cultural or heritage goods, in which the non-use value prevails and for which it is preferable to use other methods such as the contingent valuation method7. Finally, its application is cheaper than other methods, in particular contingent valuation methods. This method has been developed from a suggestion made by Hotelling (1947). This au­ thor suggested using the travel cost incurred by individuals when visiting a recreation site as an implicit price for the services of that site. Exploiting the empirical relationship between increased travel distances and associated declining visitation rates would allow for the esti­ mation of the demand relationship. In this way, the Marshallian demand curve for the recre­ ation service can be estimated and appropriate consumer surplus measures calculated and thus provide a basis for comparing them with the cost of their supply. Two major variants of the TCM are the zonal travel cost method (ZTCM) and the indi­ vidual travel cost method (ITCM). A general reduced-form demand function relates visita­ tion rates (VR) to travel cost (TC) and other relevant variables (Xi) and can be specified as: VRi = α + β1TCi + β2X2i + β3X3i + ... + εi [1] where α is the intercept, the β’s are the regression parameters and εi is the error term indi­ cating each zone or individual (Perman et al., 1999). In the ZTCM, the area surrounding the recreation site is divided into various zones. Each zone has an average travel cost according to its distance from the site (Garrod and Willis, 1991). The visitation rate per zone, in a given time period, can be estimated using the aver­ age travel cost. Several authors have applied this version to estimate the demand relationship (Englin and Bowker, 1996; Bateman et al., 1999; Bennear, 2005; Inhyuck, 2007). However, this approach has two significant limitations (Ward and Bell, 2000). Firstly, there is the dif­ ficulty in accounting for the effects of travel time on individuals and secondly, the aggrega­ tion and averaging process required to estimate zonal values make certain demand determi­ Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 45 nants, particularly the socioeconomic variables, statistically non-significant. In fact, there is a loss of information efficiency. For its part, ITCM uses survey data from individual visitors to link the demand of pub­ lic goods to its determinants. The number of trips made by an individual over a given peri­ od of time may be estimated by calculating how far the visitor must travel to get to the site, the amount of time spent travelling, travel and on-site expenses, their income and other so­ cioeconomic characteristics. Therefore, this method allows the amount of visits purchased at different prices to be calculated. Two advantages of ITCM are that it follows conventional methods used by economists to estimate economics values based on market prices, and it also relies on what people actually do rather on what people say they would do in hypothet­ ical situations (Bell and Leeworthy, 1990). For these reasons and the weak theoretical foun­ dation of the behavioural patterns in aggregate demand models, this version is preferred over the ZTCM (Bhat et al., 1998; Buchli et al., 2003; Nillesen et al., 2005, etc.). Moreover, eco­ nomic theory shows individual models to be superior to zonal models (Fletcher, et al., 1990). In this sense, empirical studies provide mixed results. For example, the ZTCM is considered more appropriate to estimate consumer surplus when visits are uniformly distributed, al­ though ITCM is considered more suitable for the case of multiple-destination due to the dif­ ficulty of obtaining the site-specific travel cost estimates (Cook, 2000). As the relevant literature highlights, one of the main problems preventing the use of ITCM is that individuals very often make just one visit to the good valued, the estimated de­ mand curve thereby reflecting relatively few observations other than the value one for the number of trips variable (Riera, et al., 1994; Saz and Pérez y Pérez, 1999, etc.). Such is the case with blockbuster exhibitions which, because of their limited duration and special event nature, receive very few repeat visitors. This is reflected in our case study, Kyrios, where only 6% of interviewees had visited the event more than once. This means that the demand function, estimated through the individual version of the model, does not explain visitor be­ haviour sufficiently and may not be used to calculate consumer surplus. As a result, in order to estimate the value of visitor benefits associated with this cultural event, a zonal travel cost model was chosen for the present study8. This decision should not entail any major implica­ tions, since this methodology uses relatively straightforward demand models that, given cer­ tain research objectives, can indeed perform as well as individual models (Hellerstein, 1995). We believe that this approach is appropriate as visits are uniformly distributed among Span­ ish provinces and only visitors who declared that the basic reason or purpose for their jour­ ney was to visit the ‘Ages of Mankind’ exhibition were selected from the sample. In this way, data used in this study are limited to planned visits, in which the travel cost does not involve multiple purposes. This does not pose a great problem, as one of the characteristics of these types of exhibition is actually to exercise substantial influence on willingness to travel (Boter, 2005: 25), the truncation percentage of the sample therefore being fairly small9. However, there are a number of problems that may arise when applying TCM, two of which are briefly discussed here. The first is the choice of a functional form used to estimate the demand curve. The economic theory of constrained optimisation with weak complemen­ 46 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS tarity does not imply any particular functional form for the trip generating equation. Given no a priori guidance, the functional form is decided according to which fits the data better. This decision has important implications for the results obtained and affects both the expect­ ed value and variance of consumer surplus estimates (Ziemer et al., 1980; Hanley, 1989; Adamowicz et al., 1989; Ozuna et al., 1993). Three functional forms were used to estimate the econometric model of visitor demand: linear, semilog, and exponential specification functions. Linear models are the most common­ ly used on estimations when using ordinary least square (OLS) regression. No variables need to be transformed, thus minimising potential coding errors. They are also easy to interpret for policy makers analysing visitor rates. However, linear models have been less popular over the last 20 years of published research in TCMs because the goodness of fit is poorer than nonlinear forms (Ward and Beal, 2000). This is particularly the case where there are few visits at very high prices and many visits at near-zero prices. In our case, the linear function had the least adjusted R2 compared to the other two models, leading us to reject this approximation. Semi-log models, where the dependent variable is transformed by taking the natural loga­ rithm, are commonly used in literature, such as by Ziemer, Musser and Hill (1980), Vaugh­ an, et al. (1982), Strong (1983) or Willis and Garrod (1991). This specification shows the best adjusted R2, although the test for the presence of heteroscedasticity rejects the null hypothe­ ses of homoscedasticity, which would bias parameter variance estimates and lead to incorrect statistical conclusions. We therefore also rejected this specification. The third specification presents the second best adjusted R2 after the semi logarithmic model. The exponential spec­ ification for the Clawson and Knetsch model was thus selected. The second widely discussed aspect of TCM is the specification of the monetary price of the recreation trip. There are four kinds of travel cost that could be used in a TCM study (Ward and Beal, 2000): firstly, taking account of only the cost of the petrol (petrol cost); sec­ ondly, other expenses generated by the car such as wear and tear, insurance and so on may also be added (full car running cost); we may also add other expenses incurred during the trip such as meals and accommodation (out-of-pocket cost); finally, the travel time and recre­ ational experience may also be taken into consideration (travel time cost). In all these cases, consumer surplus may vary significantly depending on the decisions taken, possibly leading to the belief that the measures obtained using this valuation method include judgements made by those conducting the analysis. This is perhaps the main criticism levelled at this ap­ proach by many authors, the most critical probably being Randall (1994: 93-95), who argues that ‘the resulting travel costs and welfare estimates remain artefacts of the travel cost ac­ counting and specifications conventions selected for imposition’ and ‘the best we can expect is ordinally measurable welfare estimates’. In order to minimize the effect of the monetary travel cost specification on the estimat­ ed welfare measures and thus be able to analyse the sensitivity of surplus measures to the pe­ cuniary cost specification, it was decided to use the four options posited in the literature. Specifically, the following types of travel cost were designed. Firstly, only the cost of the petrol was taken in to account (TCpetrol), calculated as the consumption of an average vehi­ Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 47 cle weighted in terms of the characteristics of the total number of cars in the country and prices of different car fuels. Although not the most common option in the literature, it is the most prudent. Secondly, in addition to the petrol cost, it was decided to take account of other expenses generated by the vehicle (TCfullcar), including all the expenses incurred by the ve­ hicle during the trip in terms of fuel, wear and tear, insurance and so on. Thirdly, added to these are the other expenses linked to visiting the event (TCoutofpocket), specifically accom­ modation and meal expenses incurred by the visitor as a result of making the trip. Including travel time as an element of travel cost is a more controversial issue (Bock­ stael et al., 1987; Larson, 1993; Azqueta, 1994, etc.), concerning which there is no agree­ ment. To gauge its effects on measures of surplus, estimations that included the time taken up in travel were included separately. Specifically, a percentage of the hourly wage as an ap­ proximation of the opportunity cost of the time taken up in travel was considered, following the approach employed by most authors. Given the lack of agreement regarding the value to be applied, the two most common found in the literature are used. Firstly, 20% of the hourly wage as proposed by Garrido et al. (1996), Parumog et al. (2003), etc., and secondly, 50% of the hourly wage as proposed by Cesario (1976), Riera (1997), etc. Combining various choices of travel costs and the inclusion or otherwise of travel time gave rise to nine specifications of the demand function that were estimated as follows: Ln (VRi) = α + βi * 1/TCi + β2 * INCOMEi + εi [2] where i-zones are Spanish provinces, equivalent to two digits statistical division of the Na­ tional Statistics Institute (Spanish Statistical Office). VRi are the visitation rates of area i, de­ fined as visitation per 1,000 inhabitants and calculated using the following formula: VRi = Vi + 1000 Pi [3] TCi are the vehicular travel costs, in current euros, based on several cost specifications between the capital of area i and the study site. This variable is expected to be negative, in the sense shown by economic theory. INCOMEi is the per capital gross domestic product of the i areas, in thousand current euros, used to display the effect of level of income on the de­ mand function. Therefore, the expected sign of this variable would be positive in the sense shown by economic theory. The estimated travel costs regression coefficients can be used to determine the value of the ‘Ages of Mankind’ exhibition in Ciudad Rodrigo in terms of consumer surplus. Using an evaluation technique, often known as the Hotelling-Clawson approach, the travel cost coef­ ficient is used as a measure of sensitivity of visitors to added cost, such as an entrance fee (Clawson and Knetsch, 1966). If ef is the added cost, equation (2) becomes: β̂1 +ε i α̂ + V̂i *1000 = e (TC+ef )i Pi [4] 48 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS ^ the es­ ^ and β where V^i is the estimated numbers of annual trips from area i to Kyrios and α 1 timated regression parameters. We can refer to the relationship in equation (4) as the Mar­ shallian or uncompensated demand curve which includes the income effect of a price change. Integrating this equation results in an estimate of the Marshallian consumer surplus (MCS) in the absence of an entrance fee10 (Anex, 1995). This estimation could be an accu­ rate approximation of the individual visitor’s welfare under the assumption of a free access situation. Equation (4) can be integrated as follows: MCS = max tc α̂+ β̂1 dTC e TC ∫ [5] min tc Where mintc is the travel cost of reaching the closest area i and maxtc is the cost at which no trips are demanded, also known as the choke price. Given the characteristics of the esti­ mated demand function, the choke price would be infinite. Calculation of the Marshallian consumer surplus would not be possible using an infinite choke price. To solve this problem travel cost was replaced by the maximum cost possible to access the zone from within Spain. This decision has been justified by it being unlikely that trips are demanded from a greater distance. The mathematical solution of the integration process returns the following formula to calculate the MCS of visitor to Kyrios (Frutos et al., 2009): max tc ∞ β̂1n +2 1 1 MCS = e α̂ (max tc − min tc) + β̂1 ln + ∑ − [6] n +1 min tc n =0 max tc n+1 ( n + 2)!(n + 1) min tc Once the travel costs have been discounted (NETMCS), the net Marshallian consumer surplus is calculated. The value could be considered as a safe approximation of the maxi­ mum willingness to pay for entrance to the Kyrios exhibition. In this instance, the demand function is integrated between the atc and maxtc limits, where atc is the weighted average actual travel cost. This could be considered as the maximum entrance fee which would elim­ inate visitor satisfaction (whereby they would not mind if they did not visit the exhibition). 3.2. Data Aggregation (i areas) was selected on a provincial level because in Spain there is no re­ liable statistical information to lower aggregations, except on a municipal level, although disaggregation occurs to such an extent that it does not respond to the focus of the study. Higher aggregation was possible at one digit statistical division of the National Statistics In­ stitute (Spanish Statistical Office) equivalent to Autonomous Communities level, but this ag­ gregation was rejected due to the loss of information efficiency. The total visitation Vi calculation was based on data from a survey carried out at the ex­ hibition during the period it was open to the public, using simple random sampling. To pre­ Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 49 serve the randomness of the sample, the surveys were carried out on pre-arranged days and times, alternating between a.m. and p.m. sessions, as well as weekdays and weekends to re­ flect all possible types of visitor. The surveys were performed by a group of four interview­ ers specifically trained in directly interviewing visitors leaving the exhibition. The surveys were carried out between July and November 2006. Prior to carrying out the surveys a pre­ test was performed in June, which served to make slight adjustments to the questionnaire. The questionnaire comprised 32 questions covering different aspects related to the visit and its valuation, the socio-demographic profile of visitors, travel details, visitor spending and reason for the trip. The sample consisted of 1,125 questionnaires, after incomplete or non­ valid surveys had been removed. The sample was truncated to calculate this variable as follows. We first selected inter­ viewees who had incurred some travel cost, which meant removing residents of Ciudad Ro­ drigo from the sample. As a result, only those who had travelled to visit the exhibition were considered to be visitors11. Secondly, we selected visitors who had travelled in their own ve­ hicles and excluded those who had travelled by coach as it proved impossible to attribute any access cost to them12. Finally, we selected those whose visit to the exhibition had been the basic reason or purpose of their journey. TCpetroli were calculated for a range of different types of cars under the assumption that the type of vehicle a person owns and the price of the petrol does not depend on the zone of origin and that costs per kilometre are the same across all zones. The weighted-average run­ ning cost in current euros was calculated using data from the Ministry of Industry, Tourism and Trade on distances and prices of petrol (MITT, 2006). TCfullcari was calculated using the same hypotheses, where the mean cost chosen per kilometre was that paid by various Spanish administrative bodies to their employees who are required to travel for work reasons using their own vehicle (0.19 euros). This covers all expenses incurred in terms of petrol, wear and tear, insurance, etc. generated by the vehicle during the trip. TCoutpocketi was cal­ culated by adding to the above mean expenses for accommodation and meals stated by vis­ itors during the survey. The population per zone i (Pi) and per capita domestic gross product of i zones (INCOMEi ) were collected from the National Statistics Institute (NSI, 2006). Provincial hourly wage was calculated using data taken from the Tax Authorities (AEAT, 2006) and National Statistics Institute (NSI, 2000). 4. Results The results of the ordinary least squares estimation of the demand models, described by equation (2) for all travel cost specification, are presented in Table 3. The models were evaluated using several criteria, including explanatory power (adjust­ ed R2) and significance (F-value). In the first case, the explanatory power proved very high 50 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS for all models with an adjusted R2 between 0.763 and 0.697. In the second case, F-ratio value indicated that all models were significant, particularly at the 1% level. As regards the price or travel cost coefficient estimates for each of the nine specifica­ tions, these were consistent with demand theory, in that the quantity of visitors per 1,000 in­ habitants in the area was inversely related to price or travel cost. Intercepts and travel cost coefficients were significant at the 1% level. In relation to provincial per-capita income, the coefficients were significant at 1% level and the signs are positive, in line with consumer be­ haviour. The models were tested for heteroscedasticity because travel cost models with unequal populations often lack homoscedasticity, caused by the difference in visitation rates from zones with larger populations being greater than in zones with smaller populations (Bowes and Loomis, 1980; Vaughan, et al., 1982). This problem is also common when there are vari­ ations in visitation rates between zones (Christensen and Price, 1982). The correlation be­ tween dependent variables predicted adjusted values and standardised residuals regression, using Pearson’s correlation coefficient, were insignificant at the 95% significance level for all models. Heteroscedasticity is not, therefore, considered a problem for this analysis. Models were also tested for autocorrelation, using the Durbin-Watson test, and residu­ als normality absence, using the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test with the standardised residuals sample. The applied test rejected the presence of these problems, and so models are believed to be valid for prediction making and the Marshallian consumer surplus is calculated in terms expressed in formula number 6. Table 2 VARIABLE SUMMARY STATISTICS (EQUATION 2) Variable name LnVR 1/TCpetrol 1/TCpetrol(20%wage/hour) 1/TCpetrol(50%wage/hour) 1/TCfullcar 1/TCfullcar(20%wage/hour) 1/TCfullcar(50%wage/hour) 1/TCoutofpocket 1/TCoutofpocket(20%wage/hour) 1/TCoutofpocket(50%wage/hour) INCOME (in thousand euros) Dependent variable LnVR. Source: Own elaboration. Mean Standard deviation –2.4767 0.0175 0.0140 0.0108 0.0074 0.0067 0.0059 0.0051 0.0048 0.0043 18.8033 1.2556 0.0131 0.0100 0.0810 0.0055 0.0049 0.0043 0.0031 0.0029 0.0027 3.8301 Upper boundary Lower boundary Value Upper boundary Lower boundary Value Upper boundary Lower boundary Value Statistic value (t-value) Dependent variable LnVR. Source: Own elaboration. F–statistic R–squared Adjusted R–squared Significance level Durbin–Watson INCOME 1/TC Intercept Variable 0.159 47.144 0.718 0.703 99% 2.049 48.205 0.723 0.708 99% 2.029 0.099 (3.356 0.093 (3.198) 0.152 0.039 0.034 125.622 103.832 (9.655) 83.256 (9.763) 100.535 82.041 65.978 –4.542 –5.796 (–9.366) –5.686 (–9.347) –4.453 –7.050 20% wage/hour –6.919 Only petrol TCPetrol 45.919 0.713 0.697 99% 2.066 0.165 0.104 (3.482) 0.044 163.054 134.460 (9.528) 105.866 –4.616 –5.892 (–9.353) –7.168 50% wage/hour 48.205 0.723 0.708 99% 2.029 0.152 0.093 (3.198) 0.034 238.770 197.734 (9.763) 156.697 –4.453 –5.686 (–9.347) –6.919 Only fullcar 47.743 0.721 0.706 99% 2.038 0.155 0.096 (3.276) 0.037 263.923 218.382 (9.716) 172.840 –4.497 –5.739 (–9.361) –6.982 20% wage/hour TCfullcar 47.117 0.718 0.703 99% 2.050 0.159 0.099 (3.362) 0.039 301.563 249.241 (9.652) 196.919 –4.546 –5.801 (–9.368) –7.055 50% wage/hour 60.529 0.776 0.763 99% 1.615 0.146 0.091 (3.385) 0.036 438.548 370.080 (10.973) 301.611 –4.902 –6.081 (–10.475) –7.259 60.355 0.775 0.762 99% 1.645 0.148 0.094 (3.467) 0.039 465.105 392.402 (10.957) 319.700 –4.922 –6.105 (–10.483) –7.287 Only 20% outofpocket wage/hour TCcoutofpocket 59.735 0.773 0.760 99% 1.686 0.152 0.096 (3.553) 0.041 504.444 425.257 (10.901) 346.051 –4.939 –6.129 (–10.459) –7.318 50% wage/hour Table 3 ORDINARY LEAST SQUARES ESTIMATE FOR KYRIOS MODELS: SUMMARY MODELS AND DEMAND PARAMETERS Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 51 52 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS The results of the integration process between minimum-maximum and actual-maxi­ mum travel cost are presented in Table 4. Consumer surplus range varies between the 27.85 € (TCpetrol without travel time) to 93.23 € (TCoutofpocket and travel time 50% wage per hour) where the mean for all travel cost specifications reaches a value of 63.64 €. Based on these data, total benefits from the event could be estimated as approximately 30 million euros, with a variation ranging between 13 and 44 million depending on the cost specification used. With regards to the net Marshallian consumer surplus (NMCS), visitors would have been willing to pay a mean entrance fee of 7.72 euros to visit the exhibition, with a range be­ tween 3.36 euros (TCpetrol without travel time) and 10.34 euros (TCoutofpocket and travel time 50% wage per hour). Hypothetically speaking, the organisation of this event could have obtained revenue, based on entrance fees, between 1.8 and 4.8 million euros depending on the cost specification used, with a mean of around 3.6 million euros. As regards the sensitivity of the surplus value to the specification of the cost function, the highest specifications (TCoutofpocket) almost triple the most conservative (TCpetrol), the former being 2.5 times greater than the latter. Specifically, without taking account of the travel time value, the differences are identical to those reported by English and Bowker (1996), where the highest surplus values are 2.79 greater than the lowest. The studies of Pérez y Pérez et al. (1996a) or Saz and Pérez y Pérez (1999) follow a similar line, the mean values being 3 and 2.6 times greater. Differences are lower in the studies of Pérez y Pérez et al. (1996b) or Riera et al. (1994), ranging between 1.9 and 1.5 respectively. As regards the impact of including travel time cost in the surplus value, sensitivity is lower, values ranging between 7% and 50% depending on the cost specification and percent­ age of hourly wage used. This sensitivity is lower than that obtained by other authors such as Garrido et al. (1996), whose findings show that the surplus value may be twice as great depending on the percentage of hourly wage used in the cost function. Estimation of the elasticities of the exhibition demand provides interesting information related to the response of visitors to variables such as price and income (see Table 5). The price elasticity of the demand function for Kyrios is close to one (-1.196). This demand func­ tion of unitary elasticity shows that the increase or decrease in the number of visitors to the exhibition is proportional to the increase or decrease in the travel cost. Therefore, an increase in access cost for the visitor, by increasing a hypothetical entrance fee forming part of the travel cost, would reduce the number of visitors in the same proportion and would not affect revenue significantly. It should be noted however, that entrance fees usually represent a rel­ atively small part of the total costs which are involved in this type of activity13 (O’Hagan, 1995; Albi, 2003; Prieto and Fernández, 2006), so it is likely that although demand is sensi­ tive to total price, i.e. expenditure for the overall trip, it may be less sensitive to changes in entrance fees (Blattberg and Broderick, 1991; Frey and Meier, 2006)14. This low elasticity would provide a margin for special exhibition managers to increase revenue by raising entrance fees (Frey, 2000)15. TCoutofpocket TCfullcar TCpetrol TCoutofpocket TCfullcar TCpetrol TC specification Source: Own elaboration. NETMCS MCS Individual visitor welfare measurement maxtc 154.6 193.2 250.97 367.08 405.72 463.49 463.72 495.72 553.49 MCS MEAN 154.6 193.2 250.97 367.08 405.72 463.49 463.72 495.72 553.49 NETMCS MEAN mintc/atc 14.1 17.74 23.25 33.44 37.1 42.61 62.44 66.1 71.61 77.83 97 125.76 184.86 204.02 232.78 250.8 270.1 299.05 Travel Time Only petrol 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only fullcar 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only outofpocket 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only petrol 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only fullcar 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only outofpocket 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour 1.88 2.35 3.88 4.46 4.94 5.64 4.32 4.65 5.31 4.16 8.72 10.37 12.82 20.74 21.56 24.83 23.37 25.22 28.05 19.52 Minimum 3.36 4.24 6.98 7.97 8.86 10.18 8.47 9.1 10.34 7.72 27.85 33.17 40.83 66.39 70.19 79.36 77.76 83.99 93.23 63.64 Mean Table 4 INDIVIDUAL VISITOR WELFARE ESTIMATES FOR KYRIOS (in current euros) 6.01 7.66 12.57 14.27 15.92 18.4 16.66 17.82 20.15 14.38 103.25 123.33 151.96 246.61 263.8 295.2 286 309.57 344.38 236.01 Maximum Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 53 54 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS Table 5 ELASTICITIES FOR KYRIOS DEMAND MODELS TC specification TCpetrol TCfullcar TCoutofpocket Travel Time Price elasticity* Income elasticity* Only petrol 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only fullcar 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour Only outofpocket 20% wage/hour 50% wage/hour –1.0696 –1.0704 –1.0692 –1.0696 –1.0703 –1.0707 –1.4756 –1.4528 –1.4220 1.7487 1.8615 1.9555 1.7487 1.8051 1.8615 1.7111 1.7675 1.8051 MEAN –1.1967 1.8072 * Elasticities evaluated at mean. Source: Own elaboration. Demand price elasticities hardly varies with regard to the specification of chosen travel cost, the values obtained proving virtually identical for the specifications TCpetrol and TC­ fullcar. If we take account of all the expenses (TCoutofpocket), the demand function becomes slightly more elastic, with values approaching –1.4. This might be because the greater the distance which visitors have to travel, the proportionally more other expenses linked to the trip, particularly accommodation and meals, are likely to rise. This would lead to a sharp­ er reduction in the participation rate due to increased travel costs. The value of price elastic­ ity do not vary either if we take into consideration or not the cost of travel time value and the percentage of hourly wage chosen. The income elasticity is positive (1.807), indicating that demand for this good can be considered normal, in line with empirical studies carried out to date in other areas of the cul­ tural sector which also usually give positive results for this variable (Throsby, 1994; LévyGarboua and Montmarquette, 2002; Albi, 2003; Seaman, 2006). Income elasticity above one indicates that spending on such activities increases proportionately more in relation to the increase in visitor income. Temporary exhibitions would therefore be considered luxury goods, which are consumed regularly by consumers with medium to high incomes (Heilbrun and Gray, 1993). The value of income elasticity obtained supports the positive growth ex­ pectations for this sector (Frey and Meier, 2006) and also relates to the boom in demand for this type of activity with the increase in real income which has occurred in recent decades (Frey, 2000). In this case, there are again no differences depending on the cost specification chosen. Values are thus very similar for the three kinds of travel cost used. In this case, the main dif­ ferences are in the travel time value, where there is a positive relation between the elastici­ ty value and time cost. In other words, the greater the opportunity cost of time measured in hourly wage, the more elastic to income is the demand function. Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 55 5. Conclusions and discussion The main objective of this study was to investigate the potential of the travel cost method in measuring the social benefits derived from cultural goods by its application to a specific case study: blockbuster art exhibitions. Despite the growing significance of such cultural activities, to date no study has approached their economic valuation by estimating demand function and calculating the consumer surplus associated with the provision of such goods. The authors believe that a knowledge of the demand function is fundamental for the management of this kind of cultural event. Its estimation enables calculation of individual visitor welfare under the assumption of free access in the form of Marshallian consumer surplus (MCS) or the maximum willingness to pay, through a hypothetical entrance fee that increases travel costs, in the form of net Marshallian consumer surplus (NETMCS). In the case of Kyrios, the mean MCS reaches a value of 63.64 € per visitor and the NETMCS 7.72 € per visitor. One finding to emerge was the sensitivity of consumer surplus value to the monetary cost specification. In summary, this research indicates that selection of travel cost prices is important in estimating consumer surplus. Choosing an incorrect definition can lead to a mis-specified price variable and a biased surplus estimates. This is extremely important when using TCM as a tool to calculate admission prices to such events, as this value might prove a key component in access cost and have a major impact on the decision to visit. In any case, as most authors advise, there is a need to be cautious and to choose the most con­ servative estimations when these are used as a management tool for attribute valued. The values obtained in the present study are higher than those reported by other authors. For example, using ZTCM, Prayaga et al. (2006) and Poor and Smith (2004) estimate MCS at 21 € (34.87AUD) and 13 € (19.26USD) per visitor16 to a special event in Queensland (Australia) and a cultural heritage site in Maryland (USA) respectively. Using ITCM, Paru­ mog, Cal and Mizokami (2003) or Alberini and Longo (2006) calculate this value at 4 € (260.19PHP) per visitor to two cultural heritage sites in Cebu (Philippines) or 32.37 € (18,440AMD) per visitor to four cultural heritages in Armenia respectively. These differ­ ences might reflect the tremendous cultural and social value that citizens attach nowadays to blockbusters exhibitions. Comparison of the sensitivity of the estimated demand function to price throws up con­ tradictory results. Poor and Smith (2004), obtain a practically identical demand function of unitary elasticity (–1.074) to that obtained in this study. Parumog et al. (2003) however, es­ timate a highly price-elastic demand function with an average value for both sites of –6.896. Both studies consider culture as an inferior good, obtaining negative income elas­ ticities (–0.749 and –6.393) in both instances. This differs substantially from our findings in particular and generally from literature on the topic, in which the different types of cul­ tural activities usually have positive and in many cases high elasticities. We believe that our findings are more in line with reality. It is more normal for cultural products to be luxuries rather than inferior goods, given that they are more widely consumed in more highly devel­ 56 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS oped countries. Societies usually begin to concern themselves with culture and cultural her­ itage preservation once other basic needs have been dealt with (Greffe, 1990: 63). The elas­ ticity of these types of goods would be more similar to items consumed when the income per capita starts to increase, for example all consumer goods and services related to leisure and recreation. The results of our work evidence that TCM is a suitable technique for estimating con­ sumer surplus derived from blockbuster arts exhibitions. The findings to emerge from our work specifically highlight the important social benefits linked to staging special exhibi­ tions. We believe that this method can be used to value other types of temporary activities and cultural events capable of attracting a significant number of visitors to where they are held and in which the use value or benefits are significant. As with other non-market valua­ tion methods, TCM displays huge potential as a tool for cultural planning. Actually, in re­ cent years the economic valuation of cultural goods and services has gained in relevance within cultural policy. Applying this approach provides valuable information for cultural managers and policy-makers. Firstly, it provides an estimation of the demand for cultural goods and their elasticities. This information will enable prediction of future trends and may contribute towards designing successful pricing strategies for cultural activities. The con­ sumer surplus calculation allows the comparison of the social benefits derived from this type of activity with its costs, which may help to assign public resources in a more rational man­ ner. The satisfaction derived by consumers or visitors to cultural activities can also be esti­ mated and used to compare different cultural institutions and projects in terms of their abil­ ity to satisfy the wants and preferences of the general public. Our study clearly has its limitations and leaves the way open for future research oppor­ tunities. As highlighted throughout our work, despite its enormous potential for valuing cul­ tural goods, TCM also evidences certain limitations. TCM only reflects visitor use values to emerge from the supply of cultural goods, excluding non-use values which, on occasions, might prove significant. In this sense, the method underestimates demand and therefore, the social benefits linked to the supply of cultural goods. Although estimating the use value of blockbuster exhibitions in itself can provide valuable information, in order to gain a deeper insight into the social benefits to emerge from the provision of such cultural goods addition­ al non-market techniques could be employed, amongst which the contingent valuation method is the most logical choice. One area of future research into the valuation of the so­ cial benefits provided by blockbuster exhibitions would thus be to conduct a contingent val­ uation study. It should also be pointed out that estimating the total economic value of this kind of exhibition also involves taking account of the positive externalities to emerge from hosting such cultural projects for society as a whole. One of the most important is the major indirect economic benefit for the regional and/or local economy that such events can gener­ ate given their enormous tourist appeal. A further interesting area of future research would be to explore the economic impact of this kind of exhibition. Jointly with the application of non-market techniques, this approach would provide more comprehensive information con­ cerning the economic and social benefits linked to the staging of this kind of cultural proj­ ect. Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 57 Notes 1.­ Please refer to compilations from Noonan (2002) or Snowball (2008), among others. 2.­ This technique has been applied recently to measure the benefits of a special event, the Gemfest in Queens­ land (Australia) (Prayaga, Rolfe and Sinden, 2006), although since it concerns a jewellery fair it does not ac­ tually relate to the subject of the study we are attempting to measure here. 3.­ The singularity of the pieces exhibited (which are on occasion private property) together with no opportunity to view the items again either separately or together are strong incentives for the public to visit these events in order not to miss out. The time restriction increases visitor incentives by creating a sensation of urgency (Frey, 2000). These behaviours are not observed in other types of permanent exhibitions or cultural activities, in which the decision to postpone the visit is easier as it is felt that nothing is thereby lost. 4.­ The more welcoming nature of temporary exhibitions helps to break down social and psychological barriers which hold people back from accessing art if they are unfamiliar with the art culture, allowing them to over­ come the reticence that visiting museums may cause (Frey, 2000). This phenomenon is especially true for events that take place in public spaces, which are more accessible to the general public and less intimidating than traditional centres and cultural institutions. 5.­ Although on occasions this kind of activity may lead to excess demand and therefore the possible risk of over­ crowding, the likelihood of exclusion avoids such situations. In general, regardless of whether or not an entrance fee is charged, visitor admission to events of this nature is based on their carrying capacity, calculated due to the quality of the experience and visitor comfort (García, 2001), among other aspects. This restriction on visitor number may give rise to queues at the entrance to the exhibition, yet it ensures the quality of the ex­ perience for all the visitors and maintains the non-rival consumer nature of this kind of service. As a result, the extent to which these goods are rival or non-rival will in each case depend on the conditions and levels of service in which this kind of cultural product is provided. 6.­ It should be pointed out that providing free admission to this kind of exhibition is a common practice among many institutions, and is based on a wish to disseminate culture. The decision whether or not to charge admis­ sion to the exhibition will in any case depend on the profile of the organisers, their social function and the need or otherwise to recover the expected outlay. 7.­ In these instances the demand for the cultural goods would be underestimated as they would not include non­ users omitting non-use values which, in many cases, would be significant (Ready and Navrud, 2002; Ben­ hamou, 2003). Therefore, the use of this method would be limited to valuation of sites entailing significant travel (Mourato and Mazzanti, 2002), as in this study. 8.­ This situation is quite common in the area of cultural goods and services where multiple individual visits are infrequent, and is why most studies valuing such goods and services conducted to date have also employed ZTCM (see Martin, 1994; Poor and Smith, 2004 or Forrest et al., 2000). 9.­ The TCM is based on the assumption that the travel cost to enjoy an event or cultural attraction is a satisfac­ tory proxy of the visitor’s willingness to pay (Throsby, 2001; Benhamou, 2003). This situation arises when two conditions are met: that such an event or attraction is the sole purpose of the journey and that the journey does not involve any other type of enjoyment by itself. This means that the method may only be applied to value goods which fulfil these essential assumptions to a sufficient degree (Frey, 2000). In practice, to ensure these hypotheses are complied with, many researchers work with truncated samples, choosing only those vis­ itors who state that the visit to the site or event is the basic reason or purpose for their trip. This procedure is common in other studies addressing valuation of cultural goods and special events such as the works of Poor and Smith (2004) and Prayaga, Rolfe and Sinden (2006). 10.­ The Hicksian compensating variation and equivalent variation welfare measures are the theoretically correct measures of the value of the benefits, even though Willig (1976) showed that consumer surplus is an accept­ able approximation. 11.­ TCM was originally developed to value natural spaces where no residents lived, as a result of which all the visitors incurred access costs. The two other possible alternatives would have involved, firstly, allocating the 58 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS mean cost of the sample unit (province) to which the town belongs, which would not have proved accurate and would have led to overestimations of the surplus. The second option would have been to allocate a zero trav­ el cost, which is not possible either in the provincial model used, where i corresponds to a territorial body which is determined administratively. This would have fractured the homogeneity in the disaggregation. As a result it was decided to remove the residents. 12.­ In most cases, visitors who travelled by coach formed part of organised trips subsidised in part or in full, mean­ ing that it was either impossible to calculate the true access cost or it was extremely difficult to distinguish what part of the cost of the trip corresponded to each of the items making up the total cost (petrol, meals, etc.) since the price paid by the visitor might include these or might not. Due to the “noise” which such visitors brought into the models it was decided to remove them, a practice also used by other authors such as Saz and Pérez y Pérez (1999). 13.­ It is expected that this proportion is particularly reduced for blockbuster exhibitions given the close relation­ ship with tourism. Evidence of this is the high percentage of visitors to these events who come from outside the city, from another region, and even from abroad. 14.­ Although findings from empirical studies carried out to date differ, they generally tend to support the hypoth­ esis of low price elasticity of the demand for cultural goods and services (Albi, 2003; Prieto and Fernández, 2006). Nevertheless, the majority of these studies estimate the elasticity-price of the demand for the whole of a cultural subsector, and therefore the results would vary greatly for institutions or specific cases in which greater values would be obtained and occasionally values greater than minus one (Heilbrun and Gray, 1993; Albi, 2003; Seaman, 2006). 15.­ In fact, if we analyse museum entrance fees, we see how those applied to special exhibitions are usually high­ er than for permanent exhibitions, and indeed many museums which do not normally charge entrance fees begin to do so for temporary exhibitions. 16.­ Conversion to euros has been calculated based on the official rate of exchange in October 2009. These values reflect the year in which the study was carried out and have not been updated. References Adamowicz, W., Fletcher, J. and Graham-Tomasi, T. (1989), “Functional form and the statistical prop­ erties of welfare measures”, American Journal of Agricultural Economy, 71: 414-421. Agencia Tributaria (AEAT 2006), Asalariados, percepciones salariales y salarios por provincia, Available on line at www.aeat.es. [last access: September the first, 2010]. Alberini, A. and Longo, A. (2006), “Combining the travel cost and contingent behavior methods to value cultural heritage sites: evidence from Armenia”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 30(4): 287-304. Albi, E. (2003), Economía de las Artes y Política Cultural, Madrid: Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Anex, R. (1995), “A travel-cost method of evaluating household hazardous waste disposal services”, Journal of Environmental Management, 45: 189-198. Azqueta, D. (1994), Valoración Económica de la Calidad Ambiental, Madrid: MacGraw-Hill. Bateman, I., Brainard, J., Lovet, A. and Garrod, G. (1999), “The impact of measurement assumptions upon individual travel cost estimates of consumer surplus: a GIS analysis”, Regional Environment Change, 1(1): 24-30. Belcher, M. (1994), Organización y diseño de exposiciones. Su relación con el museo, Gijón: Edi­ ciones Trea. Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 59 Bell, F. and Leeworthy, V. (1990), “Recreational demand by tourist of saltwater beach”, Environmen­ tal Economy and Management, 18: 189-205. Benhamou, F. (2003), “Heritage”, in Towse, R. (ed.), A Handbook of Cultural Economics, Chel­ tenham: Edward Elgar, 255-262. Bennear, L. (2005), “Using Revealed Preferences to Infer Environmental Benefits: Evidence from Recreational Fishing Licences”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 28(2): 157-179. Bhat, G., Bergstrom, J., Teasley, R., Bowker, J. and Cordel, H. (1998), “An ecoregional approach to the economic valuation of land-and water-based recreation in the United States”, Environmental Management, 22(1): 69-77. Blattberg, R. C. and Broderick, C. J. (1991), “Marketing of Arts Museums”, in Feldstein, M. (ed.), The Economics of Arts Museums, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 327-346. Bockstael, N. E., Strand, I. E. and Hanemann, W. M. (1987), “Time and recreational demand model”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 68: 293-302. Boter, J., Rouwendal, J. and Wedel, M. (2005), “Time to compare the value of competing cultural or­ ganizations”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 29(1): 19-33. Bowes, M. and Loomis, J. (1980), “A note on the use of travel cost models with unequal zonal popu­ lations”, Land Economy, 56: 465-470. Buchli, L., Filippini, M. and Banfi, S. (2003), “Estimating the benefits of low flow alleviation in rivers: the case of the Ticino river”, Applied Economics, 35(5): 585-590. Cesario, F. J. (1976), “Value of Time in Recreation Benefit Studies”, Land Economics, 52: 32-41. Chen, Y., Chen, C. and Hsieh, T. (2008), “Evaluation of the Economic Value of World Culture Her­ itage. Learning from the Example of the Great Wall of China”, The Journal of American Academy of Business, 13(2): 160-168. Christensen, J. and Price, C. (1982), “A note on the use of travel cost models with unequal zonal pop­ ulations: comment”, Land Economy, 58: 395-399. Clawson, M. and Knestch, J. (1966), Economics of outdoor recreation, Washington: Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future. Cook, A. (2000), “Estimation of community values of lakes. A study of lake Mokoan in Victoria, Aus­ tralia: a comment”, Economic Analysis and Policy, 30(1): 99-102. Cuccia, T. and Signorello, G. (2002), “Methods for measuring the demand for the arts and heritage: theorical issues”, in Rizzo, I. and Towse, R. (eds.), The Economics of Heritage. A study in the Po­ litical Economy of Culture in Sicily, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 119-146. Englin D. and Bowker, J. (1996), “Sensivity of whitewater rafting consumer surplus to pecuniary trav­ el cost specifications”, Journal of Environmental Management, 47: 79-91. English, D. and Bowker, J. M. (1996), “Sensivity of whitewater rafting consumer surplus to pecuniary travel cost specifications”, Journal of Environmental Management, 47: 79-91. 60 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS Fernández, V. and Prieto, J. (2004), “Análisis económico de los museos con una aplicación al estudio de sus visitantes en España”, Revista Asturiana de Economía, 29: 33-59. Fletcher, J., Adamowicz, W. and Graham-Tomasi, T. (1990), “The travel cost model of recreation de­ mand: theoretical and empirical issues”, Leisure Sciences, 12: 119-147. Forrest, D., Grime, K. and Woods, R. (2000), “Is it worth subsidising regional repertory theatre?”, Ox­ ford Economic Papers, 52(2): 381-397. Frey, B. S. (2000), Arts and Economics, Berlin: Springer. Frey, B. S. and Busenhart, I. (1996), “Special Exhibitions and festivals: Cultures’s Booming Path to Glory”, in Ginsburgh, V. A. and Menger, P.-M. (eds.), Economics of the Arts. Selected Essays, Am­ sterdam: Elsevier, 275-302. Frey, B. S. and Meier, S. (2006), “The economics of museums”, in Ginsburgh, V. A. and Throsby, D. (eds.), Handbook of the economics of art and culture, Amsterdam: North Holland, 1017-1047. Frey, B. S. and Pommerehne, W. W. (1989), Muses and Markets, Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd. Frutos, P. de, Martínez, F., Ortega, O. and Esteban, S. (2009), “Estimating the social benefits of recre­ ational harvesting of edible wild mushrooms using travel cost methods”, Investigaciones agrarias. Sistemas y recursos forestales, 18(3): 235-246. García, E. (2000), “El turismo cultural en Castilla y León. El caso singular de Las Edades del Hom­ bre”, in Iglesias, J. M. (ed.), Actas de los X cursos monográficos sobre Patrimonio Histórico, San­ tander: Universidad de Cantabria, 147-167. García, M. (2001): “Capacidad de acogida turística y gestión de flujos de visitantes en conjuntos mon­ umentales: el caso de La Alhambra”, PH. Boletín del Instituto Andaluz del Patrimonio Histórico, 36: 124-137. Garrido, A., Gómez-Limón, J., Lucio, J. V., and Múgica, M. (1996), “Estudio del Uso y Valoración del Parque Regional de la Cuenca Alta del Manzanares (Madrid) mediante el Método del Coste del Viaje”, in Azqueta, D. and Pérez y Pérez, L., Gestión de Espacios Naturales. La Demanda de Ser­ vicios Recreativos, Madrid: McGraw-Hill. Garrod, G. and Willis, K. (1991), Economic Valuation of the environment: methods and case studies, Massachusetts: Edgar Elgar. Greffe, X. (1990), La valeur économique du Patrimoine, Paris: Ed. Anthropos. Hanley, N. (1989), “Valuing rural recreation benefits: an empirical comparison of two approaches”, Journal of Agricultural Economy, 40(3), 361-374. Heilbrun, J. and Gray, C. M. (1993), The Economics of Arts and Culture. An American Perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hellerstein, D. (1995), “Welfare estimates using aggregate and individuals-observation models: a com­ parison using Monte Carlo analysis”, American Journal of Agricultural Economy, 77(3): 620-630. Hotelling, H. (1947), The economics of public recreation, The Prewitt report, Washington: National Parks Service. Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 61 Inhyuck, H. (2007), “Recreational demand for a gulf coast tourism destination”, Journal of economics and economic education research, 8(1): 51-63. Johnson, P. S. (2003), “Museums”, in Towse, R. (ed.), A Handbook of Cultural Economics, Chel­ tenham: Edward Elgar, 315-320. Larson, D. M. (1993), “Joint recreation choices and implied values of time”, Land Economics, 69: 270-286. Lévy-Garboua, L. and Montmarquette, C. (2002), “The Demand for the Arts”, CIRANO, Scientific Se­ ries, 10. Available on line at www.cirano.qc.ca/pdf/publication/2002s-10.pdf Martin, F. (1994), “Determining the size of museum subsidies”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 18(4): 255-270. MITT (Minister of Industry, Tourism and Trade) (2006), Inter-province distances and prices of petrol [on line]. Available on line at www.mityc.es [last access: December the first, 2009]. Mourato, S. and Mazzanti, M. (2002), “Economic valuation of cultural heritage: evidence and prospects”, in De la Torre, M. (2002), Assessing the values of cultural heritage, Los Ángeles, Ca: The Getty Conservation Institute. National Statistics Institute (NSI, 2000), Survey on job time, Available on line at www.ine.es. [last ac­ cess: September the first, 2010]. Netzer, D. (1978), The Subsidized Muse, Cambridge, Ma: Cambridge University Press. Nillesen, E., Wesseler, J. and Cook, A. (2005), “Estimating the recreational-use value for hiking in Belleden Ker National Park, Australia”, Environmental Management, 36(2): 311-316. Noonan, D. S. (2002), “Contingent valuation studies in the arts and culture: an annotated bibliogra­ phy”, Cultural policy center, University of Chicago, Working paper, 11. NSI (National Statistics Institute) (2006): Statistical use of the Continuous Municipal Register files, Available on line at www.ine.es. [last access: December the first, 2009]. O’Hagan, J. W. (1995), “National Museums: To Charge or Not To Charge?”, Journal of Cultural Eco­ nomics, 19(1): 33-47. Ozuna, T., Jones, L. and Capps, O. (1993), “Functional form and welfare measures in truncated recre­ ation models”, American Journal of Agricultural Economy, 75: 1.030-1.035. Parumog, M. G., Cal, P. C., Mizokami, S. (2003), “Using travel cost and contingent valuation method­ ologies in valuing externalities of urban road development: an application in valuing damages to cul­ tural heritage”, Journal of the Eastern Asia Society for Transportation Studies, 5: 2.948-2.961. Peacock, A. (1969), “Welfare Economics and Public Subsidies to the Arts”, Manchester School of Eco­ nomic and Social Studies, December, 323-35. Pearce, D., Mourato, S., Navrud, S. and Ready, R. C. (2002), “Review of existing studies, their policy use and future research needs”, in Navrud, S. and Ready, R.C. (eds.), Valuing Cultural Heritage: Applying Environmental Valuation Techniques to Historic Buildings, Monuments and Artefacts, Northampton: Edward Elgar, 257-270. 62 EVA VICENTE AND PABLO DE FRUTOS Pérez y Pérez, L., Barreiro, J., Sánchez, M. and Azpilikueta, M. U. (1996b), “La valeur d´usage á des fins de loisir des espaces protégés en Espagne. Comparision entre méthode des coûts de déplacement et méthode d´évaluation contingente”, Cahiers d´Economie et Sociologie Rurales, 41: 40:56. Pérez y Pérez, L., Barreiro, J., Álvarez-Farizo, B. and Barberán, R. (1996a), “El Valor de Uso Recrea­ tivo del Parque Nacional de Ordesa y Monte Perdido. Coste del Viaje versus Valoración Contingen­ te”, in Azqueta D. and Pérez y Pérez, L, Gestión de Espacios Naturales. La Demanda de Servicios Recreativos, Madrid: McGraw-Hill. Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J. and Common, M. (1999), Natural resources and environmental economics, New York: Pearson education Inc. Poor, P. J. and Smith, J. M. (2004), “Travel Cost Analysis of a Cultural Heritage Site: The Case of His­ toric St. Mary’s City of Maryland”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 28: 217-229. Prayaga, P., Rolfe, J. and Sinden, J. (2006), “A travel cost analysis of the value of special events: Gem­ fest in Central Queensland”, Tourism Economics, 12(3): 403-420. Prieto-Rodríguez, J. and Fernández-Blanco, V. (2006), “Optimal pricing and grant policies for muse­ ums”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 30: 169-181. Randall, A. (1994), “A difficulty with the travel cost method”, Land Economy, 70: 88-96. Ready, R. C. and Navrud, S. (2002), “Methods for valuing cultural heritage”, in Navrud, S. and Ready, R.C. (eds.), Valuing Cultural Heritage: Applying Environmental Valuation Techniques to Historic Buildings, Monuments and Artefacts, Northampton: Edward Elgar, 10-28. Riera, P. (1997), “El valor del tiempo de desplazamiento al campo español”, Revista Española de Economía Agraria, 179: 191-201. Riera, P., Descalzi, C. and Ruiz, A. (1994), “El valor recreativo de los espacios de interés natural en España. Aplicación de la valoración contingente y del coste del desplazamiento”, Revista Española de Economía, Monográfico Recursos Naturales y Medio Ambiente: 207-229. Saz, S. del and Pérez y Pérez, L. (1999), “El Valor de Uso Recreativo del Parque Natural de l’Albufera a través del Método Indirecto del Coste del Viaje”, Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 11: 41-62. Seaman, B. A. (2006), “Empirical studies of demand for performing arts”, in Ginsburg, V. A. and Throsby, D. (eds.), Handbook of the economics of art and culture, 1, Amsterdam: North-Holland. Skinner, S. J. (2006), “Estimating the real growth effects of blockbuster art exhibits: a time series ap­ proach”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 30: 109-125. Snowball, J. D. (2008), Measuring the value of culture, Berlin: Springer. Stanley, D., Rogers, J., Smeltzer, S. and Perron, L. (2000), “Win, place or show: gauging the econom­ ic success of the Renoir and Barnes art exhibits”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 24(3): 243-255. Strong, E. (1983), “A note on the functional forms of travel cost method with zones of unequal popu­ lations”, Land Economy, 59: 342-349. Throsby, D. (1994), “The production and consumption of the arts: a view of Cultural Economics”, Journal of Economic Literature, XXXII, 1-29. Application of the travel cost method to estimate the economic value of cultural goods 63 Throsby, D. (2001), Economía y Cultura, Madrid: Cambridge University Press. Tobelem, J. M. (2005), “Les expositions temporaires. Un outil stratégique pour les musées”, Cahier Espaces, 87: 134-140. Tobelem, J. M. (2006), “Museum expansion and the economics of exhibits”, 14th International Con­ ference of the Association for Cultural Economics International, Vienna. Vaughan, W., Russell, C. and Hazilla, M. (1982), “A note on the use of travel cost models with un­ equal zonal populations. Comment”, Land Economy, 8: 400-407. Vicente, E. (2007), Economía del Patrimonio Cultural y Políticas Patrimoniales, Madrid: Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Vicente, E., Carrascal, U. and Vicente, A. (2007), Economics and social benefits of “Ages of Mankind” exhibition in Ciudad Rodrigo, Study funding by the Directorate General for Cultural Heritage, Re­ gional Ministry of Culture and Tourism of Castile and Leon, Spain. Wall, G. and Roberts, C. (1985), “The economic impact of the Tutankhamen and Van Gogh Exhibi­ tions”, in Hendon, W. S., Grant, N. K. and Shaw, D. V. (eds.), The Economics of Cultural Indus­ tries, Akron, Oh: University of Akron, 66-76. Ward, F. and Beal, D. (2000), Valuing nature with travel cost models. A manual, Cheltenham, UK: Ed­ ward Elgar. Willig, R. (1976), “Consumer’s surplus without apology”, American Economic Review, 66: 589-597. Willis, K. and Garrod, G. (1991), “An individual travel-cost method of evaluating forest recreation”, Journal of Agricultural Economy, 42: 33-42. Ziemer R., Musser, W. and Hill, R. (1980), “Recreational demand equations: functional form and con­ sumer surplus”, American Journal of Agricultural Economy, 62: 136-141. Resumen En los últimos años un número creciente de trabajos han aplicado técnicas de valoración de no merca­ do para estimar el valor económico de los bienes culturales. La mayoría utilizan técnicas de preferen­ cias declaradas, como el método de valoración contingente. En este trabajo se aplica el método del coste del viaje para estimar el valor económico de un tipo concreto de bienes culturales: las exposicio­ nes especiales. El trabajo empírico se centra en el caso específico del ciclo expositivo “Las Edades del Hombre”, uno de los primeros y más representativos ejemplos de exposición blockbuster en España. Esta es la primera vez que este método se utiliza para valorar una gran exposición temporal y una de sus escasas aplicaciones en la valoración de bienes culturales. Palabras clave: exposiciones temporales blockbuster, técnicas de valoración de no mercado, preferen­ cias reveladas, método del coste del viaje, economía de la cultura. Clasificación JEL: H41, D60, Z11